10.08.2013 Views

Pay for Quality

Pay for Quality

Pay for Quality

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

88 <strong>Pay</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>Quality</strong> KCE Reports 118<br />

Secondly, if baseline uptake is high, the mean absolute change in utilisation needed <strong>for</strong><br />

an indicator to be cost-effective needs to be larger than when the baseline uptake is<br />

low, because physicians also receive an incentive <strong>for</strong> those patients <strong>for</strong> whom the target<br />

was already reached and no additional health benefits have been achieved. As a result a<br />

high absolute change (and thus a high additional health gain) is required to compensate<br />

<strong>for</strong> the payments without extra health gain. It must also be noted that cost-effectiveness<br />

of an indicator will be partly determined by the duration of the P4Q programme. To be<br />

cost-effective it is desirable to adjust the payment according to the observed utilisation<br />

levels throughout time.<br />

We can conclude that P4Q programmes seem to be cost-effective. It can be stated that<br />

implementing indicators with a low baseline achievement, have the highest potential to<br />

be cost-effective. Since these conclusions are based on only three studies, it is<br />

recommended to augment the number of cost-effectiveness evaluations of P4Q<br />

programmes in the future.<br />

Kahn et al. (2006) 229 modelled the financial gains and losses <strong>for</strong> hospitals, using two<br />

P4Q programmes. In both programmes, urban hospitals are more likely to attract<br />

bonuses as well as to get penalties resulting in a financial gain in one programme and a<br />

small financial loss in the other programme. Rural hospitals, receive less bonuses, but<br />

also less penalties, resulting in a small financial gain in both programmes. Teaching<br />

hospitals are more likely to have a financial gain unlike non teaching hospitals, which<br />

receive a larger amount of bonuses but also get more penalties, resulting in a small<br />

financial loss in both programmes. Finally government and investor-owned hospitals are<br />

more likely to suffer a financial loss, in contrast to tax-exempt hospitals that are more<br />

likely to experience a financial gain.<br />

The payment reduction, as a result of a new inpatient prospective payment system was<br />

estimated by Averill et al. (2006) 95 . The new system provides hospitals with a financial<br />

incentive to reduce complications and to improve the quality of care. This resulted in a<br />

reduction of the Medicare DRG hospital payment with approximately 1%. These savings<br />

have the potential to increase payments to high per<strong>for</strong>ming hospitals.<br />

According to Fleetcroft et al. (2006) 227 , QOF payments don’t reflect likely health gain.<br />

The use of ACE inhibitors in heart failure relates to a maximum of 308 lives saved per<br />

100 000 people per year and is linked to a maximum payment of £2 400 per practice<br />

per year. In contrast the screening and treatment of hypertension only saves a potential<br />

maximum of 71 lives per 100 000 people per year but costs on average £17 280 per<br />

practice per year.<br />

As a result the GPs might focus on the highly rewarded indicators with sometimes<br />

relatively low population health gain.<br />

McElduff et al. (2004) 228 estimated the health gain among cardiovascular disease (CVD)<br />

patients within QOF. Reaching the target concerning cholesterol-level and hypertension<br />

would result in important reduction in number of CVD events. Fleetcroft et al. (2008)<br />

226 , 228 confirm the potential <strong>for</strong> significant health gain regarding clinical indicators. The<br />

difference between actual health gain and potential health gain can be explained by<br />

several determinants among which the room <strong>for</strong> improvement (baseline activity) and<br />

the prevalence of conditions or associated event risk. Additionally, the possibility of<br />

exception reporting within QOF reduces the potential maximum health gain.<br />

Furthermore, better recording rather than actual improved per<strong>for</strong>mance could increase<br />

the achievement. Gaming among practitioners could also influence the health gain. The<br />

health gain in patients with multiple conditions may be less or more than the sum of the<br />

beneficial effect of each intervention. And, finally, some indicators have potential side<br />

effects, which could reduce health gain (e.g. adverse events of some drugs).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!