Waste Management Committee Newsletter - American Bar Association

Waste Management Committee Newsletter - American Bar Association Waste Management Committee Newsletter - American Bar Association

apps.americanbar.org
from apps.americanbar.org More from this publisher
06.08.2013 Views

Vol. 9, No. 2 MESSAGE FROM THE NEWSLETTER VICE CHAIRS Theodore Hadzi-Antich Co-Vice Chair, Newsletters Andrew M. Kenefick Co-Vice Chair, Newsletters akenefick@wm.com We are happy to offer this newsletter regarding the latest and greatest developments in the world of waste. The selections herein may be viewed as a five-course meal. We begin with a short appetizer comprised of welcoming words from Tom Bruen, our committee membership vice chair, followed by a bouillon comprised of a message from Stephen Mossman, our committee chair, after which we serve the main course prepared by Polly McNeill and David Wiley, regarding an important case from the Washington State Supreme Court dealing with municipal franchises for the collection of construction and demolition wastes. The vegetable of the day is a review of greenhouse gas emission reduction projects at smaller landfills, offered by our own resident chef Michael McLaughlin. We conclude the meal with a desert of delectable words setting forth issues involving the disposal of waste electronic equipment, authored by our guest chef, Heather Drayton. Bon Appetit’! 1 TO OUR COMMITTEE MEMBERS Tom Bruen Vice Chair, Membership tbruen@sbcglobal.net July 2008 Welcome to the Waste Management Committee! The Waste Management committee provides a network of lawyers whose interests include developments in the solid waste and hazardous waste management field. Our committee has developed an active program for this year, including the distribution of committee newsletters, “Quick Teleconferences” where warranted by significant developments, and the committee’s submittal to the Section’s The Year in Review. We encourage other ABA members, other Section members, and other committee members who are not members of the Waste Management Committee to visit our Web site at http://www.abanet.org/environ/ committees/solidwaste/, participate with us, and join. Remember, any member of the Section can join up to five committees without additional charge. Also, if you are a member, please check with your colleagues who are not members of the Waste Management Committee and encourage them to join us.

Vol. 9, No. 2<br />

MESSAGE FROM THE<br />

NEWSLETTER VICE CHAIRS<br />

Theodore Hadzi-Antich<br />

Co-Vice Chair, <strong>Newsletter</strong>s<br />

Andrew M. Kenefick<br />

Co-Vice Chair, <strong>Newsletter</strong>s<br />

akenefick@wm.com<br />

We are happy to offer this newsletter regarding the<br />

latest and greatest developments in the world of waste.<br />

The selections herein may be viewed as a five-course<br />

meal. We begin with a short appetizer comprised of<br />

welcoming words from Tom Bruen, our committee<br />

membership vice chair, followed by a bouillon<br />

comprised of a message from Stephen Mossman, our<br />

committee chair, after which we serve the main course<br />

prepared by Polly McNeill and David Wiley, regarding<br />

an important case from the Washington State Supreme<br />

Court dealing with municipal franchises for the<br />

collection of construction and demolition wastes. The<br />

vegetable of the day is a review of greenhouse gas<br />

emission reduction projects at smaller landfills, offered<br />

by our own resident chef Michael McLaughlin. We<br />

conclude the meal with a desert of delectable words<br />

setting forth issues involving the disposal of waste<br />

electronic equipment, authored by our guest chef,<br />

Heather Drayton. Bon Appetit’!<br />

1<br />

TO OUR COMMITTEE MEMBERS<br />

Tom Bruen<br />

Vice Chair, Membership<br />

tbruen@sbcglobal.net<br />

July 2008<br />

Welcome to the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong>!<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> committee provides a<br />

network of lawyers whose interests include<br />

developments in the solid waste and hazardous waste<br />

management field. Our committee has developed an<br />

active program for this year, including the distribution<br />

of committee newsletters, “Quick Teleconferences”<br />

where warranted by significant developments, and the<br />

committee’s submittal to the Section’s The Year in<br />

Review.<br />

We encourage other ABA members, other Section<br />

members, and other committee members who are not<br />

members of the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong> to visit<br />

our Web site at http://www.abanet.org/environ/<br />

committees/solidwaste/, participate with us, and join.<br />

Remember, any member of the Section can join up to<br />

five committees without additional charge. Also, if you<br />

are a member, please check with your colleagues who<br />

are not members of the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Committee</strong> and encourage them to join us.


<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Committee</strong> <strong>Newsletter</strong><br />

Vol. 9, No. 2, July 2008<br />

Theodore Hadzi-Antich and<br />

Andrew M. Kenefick, Vice Chairs<br />

In this issue:<br />

Message from the Vice Chairs<br />

Theodore Hadzi-Antich and<br />

Andrew M. Kenefick ........................... 1<br />

To Our <strong>Committee</strong> Members<br />

Thomas M. Bruen.............................. 1<br />

Message from the Chair<br />

Stephen D. Mossman ....................... 2<br />

Washington State Supreme Court Upholds<br />

Municipal Franchises for Collection of<br />

Construction and Demolition <strong>Waste</strong>s<br />

Polly L. McNeill and David W. Wiley . 4<br />

Greenhouse Gas Emission Projects at<br />

Smaller Landfills<br />

Michael W. McLaughlin, P.E. ............ 5<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> Disposal of Electronic Equipment<br />

Heather Drayton ................................ 9<br />

© Copyright 2008. <strong>American</strong> <strong>Bar</strong> <strong>Association</strong>. All<br />

rights reserved. The views expressed herein have<br />

not been approved by the ABA House of Delegates<br />

or the Board of Governors and, accordingly should<br />

not be construed as representing the policy of the<br />

ABA.<br />

This newsletter is a publication of the ABA Section<br />

of Environment, Energy, and Resources, and<br />

reports on the activities of the committee. All<br />

persons interested in joining the Section or one of<br />

its committees should contact the Section of<br />

Environment, Energy, and Resources, <strong>American</strong><br />

<strong>Bar</strong> <strong>Association</strong>, 321 N. Clark St., Chicago, IL<br />

60654.<br />

2<br />

MESSAGE FROM THE CHAIR<br />

Stephen D. Mossman<br />

Chair, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong><br />

SDM@MattsonRicketts.com<br />

As my two-year stint as chair of the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong> (after serving three years as a<br />

committee vice chair) draws to a close, I would like to<br />

briefly reflect on the committee’s activities.<br />

2007 and 2008 have been exciting years in the field of<br />

waste management law. I would like to briefly list some<br />

of the work that the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong><br />

has accomplished:<br />

In the committee’s last newsletter, the results of<br />

a multiyear project involving a state-by-state<br />

survey of special waste with the State and<br />

Regional Environmental Cooperation<br />

<strong>Committee</strong>. Vice Chair Mike McLaughlin of<br />

SCS Engineers took the lead on this project<br />

over the years and should be commended for<br />

his dedication in seeing the project completed<br />

and distributed through several mediums.<br />

In 2007, the U.S. Supreme Court heard and<br />

decided the United Haulers case which<br />

dramatically changed the landscape of flow<br />

control of solid waste. The <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong>’s home page was the<br />

single most comprehensive source of<br />

information regarding this important decision<br />

posting all amicus and party briefs as well as<br />

detailed analyses of the arguments posed to the<br />

Court.<br />

Immediately following the issuance of the<br />

United Haulers decision, the <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong> in cooperation with<br />

the Section’s Constitutional Law <strong>Committee</strong><br />

held a Quick Teleconference on the fall out of<br />

the decision. Vice Chair David Biderman of the<br />

National Solid <strong>Waste</strong>s <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Association</strong> was one of the presenters at the<br />

Teleconference and did an excellent job of<br />

presenting issues posed by the Supreme<br />

Court’s decision.<br />

Vice Chair David Biderman was also a key<br />

presenter at the 2007 Annual Conference on


Environmental Law in Keystone, Colorado,<br />

appearing on a panel discussing waste<br />

management issues with his focus on the<br />

pending United Haulers case.<br />

The Section’s The Year in Review is one of<br />

the most important reference materials for<br />

energy, environment, and resources<br />

practitioners. The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong><br />

<strong>Committee</strong> made timely and comprehensive<br />

submissions to The Year in Review in both<br />

2006 and 2007 authored by former Vice Chair<br />

Ashley Brown Duffie and current Vice Chair<br />

Brian Collins who deserve special credit for<br />

getting their work done at a very inopportune<br />

time (right after the New Year).<br />

The committee’s membership rolls are at 197.<br />

Membership Vice Chair Tom Bruen should be<br />

commended for maintaining and expanding the<br />

committee membership.<br />

The committee issued newsletters in May and<br />

November 2007, along with this edition. Ted<br />

Hadzi-Antich for two years along with Ashley<br />

Duffie Brown and Andrew Kenefick have ably<br />

served as vice chairs for newsletter which I can<br />

tell you from past experience may be the most<br />

time consuming of vice chair duties.<br />

Vice Chair Matt Klein accepted the challenge<br />

to serve as vice chair for Public Service and<br />

has endeavored to find suitable projects.<br />

Finally, a special thank you to all vice chairs of<br />

the committee (past and present) for their<br />

dedication and hard work. You will meet many<br />

of the vice chair through their contributions to<br />

this newsletter or you can check them out on<br />

our committee’s home page at: http://www.<br />

abanet.org/environ/committees/solidwaste/.<br />

Each of the vice chairs along with other<br />

committee members made important<br />

contributions to our success.<br />

Thank you to the membership and leadership of the<br />

<strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong>. May you all continue<br />

to be involved in this important area of the law.<br />

3<br />

AMERICAN BAR ASSOCIATION<br />

SECTION OF ENVIRONMENT,<br />

ENERGY, AND RESOURCES<br />

Calendar of Section Events<br />

ABA Annual Meeting<br />

Aug. 7-12, 2008<br />

New York, New York<br />

16th Section Fall Meeting<br />

Sept. 17-20, 2008<br />

Phoenix, Arizona<br />

The Basic Practice Series<br />

Sept. 19-20, 2008<br />

Phoenix, Arizona<br />

Interdisciplinary Solutions to<br />

Instream Flow Problems<br />

Oct. 7-9, 2008<br />

San Antonio, Texas<br />

(Cosponsored with the Instream Flow<br />

Council)<br />

23rd Annual Petroleum Refining<br />

and Marketing Roundtable<br />

Oct. 15, 2008<br />

Austin, Texas<br />

(In conjunction with the 31st Annual<br />

ABA Forum on Franchising)<br />

27th Annual Water Law Conference<br />

Feb. 19-20, 2009<br />

San Diego, California<br />

38th Conference on Environmental<br />

Law<br />

March 12-15, 2009<br />

Keystone, Colorado<br />

For more information, see the<br />

Section Web site at<br />

www.abanet.org/environ or


WASHINGTON STATE SUPREME COURT<br />

UPHOLDS MUNICIPAL FRANCHISES FOR<br />

COLLECTION OF CONSTRUCTION<br />

AND DEMOLITION WASTES<br />

Polly L. McNeill<br />

Summit Law Group<br />

Seattle, Washington<br />

pollym@SummitLaw.com<br />

David W. Wiley<br />

Williams Kastner<br />

Seattle, Washington<br />

dwiley@williamskastner.com<br />

In February 2008, the Washington State Supreme<br />

Court affirmed the broad powers of local government<br />

to regulate solid waste handling, including the right to<br />

contract for collection of construction and demolition<br />

debris. In Joseph Ventenbergs et al. v. City of<br />

Seattle, <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> and Rabanco, et al.,<br />

____ Wn.2d. ____, 178 P.3d. 960 (2008), plaintiffs<br />

claimed their constitutional rights to engage in a<br />

selected livelihood were infringed by exclusive city<br />

contracts entered into between Seattle and two<br />

national waste companies. The 6-3 decision from the<br />

Washington Supreme Court upheld the city’s authority<br />

to exercise its police powers and the logical extension<br />

of that authority to prohibit other private parties from<br />

collecting demolition and construction debris from job<br />

sites.<br />

Background<br />

In Washington, solid waste collection is regulated.<br />

Cities can establish a municipal utility or enter into<br />

contracts with private parties to perform the service.<br />

In all other cases, the business is regulated by the state<br />

utility commission. Private solid waste haulers must<br />

have either a certificate of public convenience and<br />

necessity from the state, or a municipal contract.<br />

In 2001, the City of Seattle asserted jurisdiction over<br />

collection of solid waste from commercial<br />

establishments, and negotiated contracts with the two<br />

private companies that had historically performed the<br />

service under the utility commission’s oversight, <strong>Waste</strong><br />

4<br />

<strong>Management</strong> and Allied <strong>Waste</strong>. Seattle had long used<br />

private contractors for collecting from residences, and<br />

probably for that reason the definition of “City <strong>Waste</strong>”<br />

in the municipal code excluded “Construction,<br />

Demolition and Landclearing <strong>Waste</strong>” (CDL). Yet the<br />

exclusive collection rights granted to the private haulers<br />

under the commercial contracts included CDL. So, in<br />

2002, when the city learned that other companies were<br />

illegally collecting debris from construction job sites, it<br />

amended its local ordinance to clarify that the definition<br />

of “City <strong>Waste</strong>” included CDL waste. The city then<br />

sent notices to unauthorized haulers, informing them<br />

that it was unlawful for anyone other than the two<br />

contractors to haul “City <strong>Waste</strong>”—including CDL—<br />

through the streets of Seattle.<br />

Represented by the Institute for Justice’s legal<br />

department, two smaller companies sued the city, a<br />

trucking company (owned by Josef Ventenberg), and a<br />

contractor who used the unauthorized hauler (owned<br />

by Ronald Haider). They claimed that the city’s actions<br />

violated the privileges and immunities clause of the<br />

Washington state constitution in that it impermissibly<br />

bestowed benefits on the two private contractors for<br />

no good reason.<br />

The Washington State Supreme Court acknowledged<br />

the city’s broad discretion in acting under its police<br />

powers. It held that the city’s decision to contract only<br />

with the two companies in the collection of “City<br />

<strong>Waste</strong>” was reasonable, and that the city did not act<br />

improperly in limiting collection of CDL to those two<br />

businesses or otherwise violate any state constitutional<br />

provisions.<br />

Analysis<br />

Ventenbergs is consistent with other recent state<br />

supreme court decisions in the western United States<br />

honoring the rights of local government to control solid<br />

waste handling, including Douglas Disposal, Inc. v.<br />

Wee Haul, LLC, 170 P.3d. 508 (2007), WL3287566,<br />

where the Nevada Supreme Court, in reversing a<br />

lower court order, upheld the right of a municipality to<br />

exclusively contract via franchise for the collection and<br />

transportation of construction waste and disposal<br />

within the county, and found the ordinance enacting the


franchise consistent with the county’s police powers<br />

and constitutional under the dormant interstate<br />

commerce clause. The Nevada court decision is also in<br />

accord with the Idaho Supreme Court decision in<br />

Plummer v. City of Fruitland, et al., 139 id. 810, 87<br />

P.3d. 297 (2004), where the Idaho Court, on<br />

rehearing, ruled that under the state constitution, Idaho<br />

municipalities’ granting of exclusive solid waste<br />

franchises was constitutional and not in violation of<br />

other Idaho laws, including antitrust statutes, where the<br />

city was properly exercising its police power in<br />

regulating the collection of solid waste.<br />

The Washington court in Ventenbergs did not add<br />

much to the debate about whether CDL should be<br />

treated differently from putrescible waste materials.<br />

The Supreme Court recognized that CDL debris is part<br />

of the waste stream subject to local government police<br />

powers. However, the court relied on the fact that the<br />

state statutory definition of “solid waste” specifically<br />

includes CDL debris and did not otherwise rule on<br />

plaintiffs’ argument that differences between the two<br />

kinds of waste materials are legally significant. The<br />

dissent suggested that there might be merit to the<br />

argument, and in a footnote the majority deferred the<br />

question, stating only, “Should the legislature decide to<br />

remove CDL from the definition of solid waste, then<br />

perhaps we could find a distinction.”<br />

Although the Ventenbergs decision merely adds to the<br />

bulk of jurisprudence respecting the scope of local<br />

government’s police powers, it may ultimately be<br />

relevant to the other frequently-litigated issue of flow<br />

control. One of plaintiffs’ claims was that the city had<br />

impermissibly favored the two contractors in violation<br />

of the privileges and immunities clause of the state<br />

constitution. The majority of the Washington Supreme<br />

Court concluded that the right to a job in solid waste<br />

collection is not a “fundamental right” protected by the<br />

Washington constitution because the type of<br />

employment sought is not private: the power to<br />

regulate solid waste collection is vested entirely with<br />

the Washington legislature and local government, and<br />

there is no fundamental right to provide governmental<br />

services. This holding triggered the lengthy dissent,<br />

which addressed state constitutional issues not<br />

particularly pertinent to the broader implications of the<br />

Ventenbergs decision in the context of solid waste.<br />

5<br />

The authors represented before the Supreme Court<br />

the private haulers holding contracts with the City<br />

of Seattle. Ms. McNeill represented <strong>Waste</strong><br />

<strong>Management</strong> of Washington, Inc., and Mr. Wiley<br />

represented Rabanco, Ltd.<br />

GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSION<br />

REDUCTION PROJECTS AT<br />

SMALLER LANDFILLS<br />

Michael W. McLaughlin, P.E.<br />

Senior Vice President, SCS Engineers<br />

Reston, Virginia<br />

mmclaughlin@scsengineers.com<br />

Introduction<br />

Historically, smaller landfills have not had the same<br />

level of attention and opportunities as larger landfills to<br />

develop projects to productively utilize the landfill gas<br />

(LFG). With the emergence of the tidal wave of<br />

interest in climate change and specifically how<br />

voluntary control of LFG can contribute to greenhouse<br />

gas (GHG) reductions, smaller public and private<br />

landfills suddenly have a myriad of project<br />

development options. Because the smaller landfills are<br />

typically not required to collect LFG, they can make an<br />

easier claim that any collection efforts for the purpose<br />

of GHG emissions reductions are truly voluntary and<br />

thus “additional.”<br />

This article will lay out the potential options available to<br />

smaller landfills in the United States for voluntary GHG<br />

reduction projects, and summarize financial<br />

considerations. Briefly, a landfill can produce GHG<br />

reduction credits by installing a gas collection and<br />

destruction (flare) system that is not otherwise required<br />

by law or by “business as usual.” Such credits have<br />

value on the voluntary market now in the United<br />

States, and may have even greater value if and when a<br />

mandatory “cap and trade” program is implemented<br />

either regionally or nationally.<br />

The U.S. voluntary market can be further classified into<br />

two major market segments, the Chicago Climate<br />

Exchange (CCX) and the Over the Counter (OTC)


market. To date, most, if not all U.S. carbon<br />

transactions have taken place in the voluntary markets,<br />

with 23.7 million tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent<br />

(CO2e) transacted in 2006, almost 200 percent<br />

increase over 2005 levels. Of the 23.7 million tonnes<br />

CO2e transacted, the OTC market accounted for<br />

about 13.4 million tonnes and the CCX accounted for<br />

the remaining 10.3 million tonnes. The CCX traded<br />

22.9 million tonnes of CO2e in 2007. The OTC<br />

market also probably saw a doubling or tripling of<br />

volume in 2007 (K. Hamilton, R. Bayon, G. Turner,<br />

D. Higgins, “State of the Voluntary Carbon Markets<br />

2007: Picking up Steam.”).<br />

Voluntary markets trade in units called Verified<br />

Emissions Reductions (VERs). A VER is a metric<br />

tonne of CO2e. However, voluntary markets use<br />

multiple standards (protocols) for qualifying or<br />

measuring credits, and GHG credits derived under<br />

different standards may have fundamental differences<br />

(e.g., eligibility of the project, monitoring and<br />

verification requirements, price).<br />

How Markets Regard LFG Projects<br />

Landfills emit LFG-containing about 50 percent<br />

methane, and methane is a potent GHG. GHG potency<br />

is estimated in terms of its Global Warming Potential,<br />

which combines the heat retention characteristics of<br />

different gases over a particular time horizon. Under<br />

most protocols, each tonne of methane emitted by a<br />

landfill is the equivalent of 21 tonnes of CO 2 . Because<br />

it is relatively easy to measure actual reductions in<br />

methane emissions from landfills that install collection<br />

and flaring systems, theses sorts of projects are<br />

considered high quality GHG emission reduction<br />

projects.<br />

The markets are looking for landfills with the following<br />

general characteristics:<br />

The landfill (or active cell) is not required to<br />

have a LFG collection system by law (e.g., by<br />

EPA’s New Source Performance Standards<br />

(NSPS, 40 C.F.R. 60 Subpart www), or<br />

similar state or local requirements).<br />

NSPS requires that if a landfill has a design<br />

capacity of more than 2.5 million tonnes, it<br />

is required periodically to calculate its<br />

6<br />

emissions of non-methane organic<br />

compounds (NMOCs) using any of<br />

several methods. If the landfill calculates its<br />

annual NMOC emissions are no more than<br />

50 tonnes, the landfill is not subject to<br />

NSPS and thus it might be able to generate<br />

GHG credits. Under current regulations, if<br />

the landfill calculates annual emissions of<br />

more than 50 tonnes, then it has 30 months<br />

to install a gas collection and control<br />

system (but it can generate GHG credits<br />

for up to 30 months after the failed test if<br />

an “early capture” gas collection and<br />

control system is installed).<br />

The landfill can demonstrate clear ownership<br />

rights to the environmental attributes of the<br />

emissions reductions from the destruction of<br />

methane.<br />

Any existing active LFG collection systems<br />

must be voluntarily and recently installed. The<br />

CCX Standard, for example, allows an inservice<br />

date for an active LFG system of after<br />

Jan. 1, 1999. The most attractive landfills are<br />

those with no active LFG collection system.<br />

Those developing these projects (i.e., investing the<br />

capital for the LFG systems) are looking for some<br />

additional characteristics:<br />

Good landfill geometry to extract LFG<br />

efficiently—deeper is better.<br />

Sufficient waste in place (greater than<br />

1,000,000 tonnes in place).<br />

Appropriate waste composition and age—<br />

fresher is better.<br />

Good landfill management practices, with no<br />

evidence of extensive leachate issues in the<br />

waste mass.<br />

The markets favor landfill projects where a valid<br />

argument that the GHG reduction credits generated by<br />

the landfill are indeed additional. Additionally was<br />

succinctly defined by Clean Air Cool Planet as follows:<br />

Emissions reductions are “additional” if they occur<br />

because of the incentives associated with the<br />

existence of GHG markets. A variety of<br />

additionality “tests” have been proposed, but at its<br />

root demonstrating additionality means showing<br />

that the emissions reductions being used as offsets


are not “business as usual,” the concept that<br />

without the development of the GHG project,<br />

these reductions in GHG would not have otherwise<br />

occurred.<br />

Clean Air Cool Planet, “A Consumers Guide to Retail<br />

Carbon Offset Providers,” Dec. 2006.<br />

Opportunities for Landfills in the Voluntary<br />

Markets—CCX<br />

The CCX is the most visible voluntary market in the<br />

United States. The CCX functions as its own<br />

“regulated” market, where its emitting members make<br />

a voluntary, but legally binding commitment to meet<br />

annual GHG emission reduction targets. Those<br />

members who reduce below the targets have surplus<br />

allowances to sell or bank, while those who emit above<br />

the targets comply by purchasing allowances<br />

(www.chicagoclimatex.com/content.jsf?id=821).<br />

Allowances can be traded for the period 2003-2010.<br />

The CCX has its own standard, including a<br />

methodology for LFG destruction projects. It has<br />

developed its own trading unit, a Carbon Financial<br />

Instrument® (CFI®). About 9 percent of the CFI®<br />

transactions on CCX have been landfill methane<br />

projects (www.chicagoclimatex.com/offsets/<br />

projectReport.jsf).<br />

The CCX has a highly transparent financial transaction<br />

system with excellent information available on-line<br />

regarding price and volume of its CFI®s. Landfills with<br />

older legacy voluntary LFG collection systems may<br />

find the CCX protocol particularly attractive given the<br />

early in-service (on or after Jan. 1, 1999) and the<br />

ability to sell vintage credits (2003 and later).<br />

Landfill owners will most likely be required to join as<br />

full members. However, landfill owners (e.g. private<br />

owners, waste authorities) with no other major carbon<br />

emissions can join as Offset Providers at significantly<br />

lower fees. There are also lower fees for municipalities<br />

with smaller landfill projects. In 2007, membership fees<br />

were approximately $5,000 to join and $5,000 per<br />

year annual fee. Transaction fees are about $0.14/<br />

tonne.<br />

7<br />

A landfill considering joining CCX and selling its GHG<br />

reduction credits on the CCX, should consider the<br />

following advantages and disadvantages:<br />

Advantages<br />

Transparent Internet based trading<br />

platform for CFI® contracts.<br />

Relatively easy registration and verification<br />

process.<br />

Able to sell older GHG credit vintages.<br />

Earliest in-service date for a LFG<br />

collection system of all standards.<br />

Disadvantages<br />

May require a contractual obligation to<br />

reduce GHG emissions reductions by the<br />

seller (This may be an advantage to those<br />

entities that wish to show a commitment to<br />

measurable GHG reductions).<br />

Lack of transparency of the CFI® and its<br />

underlying asset. CFI®s are a commodity<br />

—a mixture of high quality actual GHG<br />

emission reduction projects and more<br />

dubious projects. Buyers cannot obtain<br />

detailed information on the underlying<br />

GHG reduction project. Buyers may be<br />

able to obtain underlying asset information<br />

after the sale.<br />

High membership and transaction costs.<br />

Potentially lower pricing when compared<br />

to OTC.<br />

Cannot sell forward w/o GHG reduction<br />

obligations.<br />

A methane potency multiplier of 18.25 vs.<br />

21 for most other voluntary standards.<br />

Opportunities for Landfills in the Voluntary<br />

Markets—OTC<br />

The OTC market offers one of the most promising<br />

areas for a landfill to sell its GHG credits. The OTC<br />

market is highly flexible and dynamic to address<br />

changing market demands by buyers and sellers. The<br />

U.S. OTC market is made up of OTC Market<br />

Participants who directly enter into agreements with<br />

landfills. OTC Market Participants include BlueSource,<br />

Ecosecurities, GE-AES Greenhouse Gas Services,<br />

Evolution Markets, NatSource, Environmental<br />

Elements, Carbon Capital Partners, and First<br />

Environment.


OTC Market Participants may structure GHG deals<br />

with landfills in any of several ways:<br />

Carbon Asset Developer—Provide all capital<br />

to install and/or expand a LFG collection and<br />

destruction system and to monitor and verify<br />

the GHG credits generated, and sell the<br />

verified GHG credits to qualified buyers over<br />

the life of the project. In return, the landfill gets<br />

an LFG collection system “for nothing,” and<br />

potentially may also receive a portion of the<br />

revenues from the GHG credit sales.<br />

Purchase the GHG Credits—The landfill<br />

provides the capital to install and/or expand a<br />

LFG collection and destruction system while<br />

the OTC Market Participant would purchase<br />

the GHG credits for a mutually agreed pricing<br />

structure and duration.<br />

Hybrid—OTC Market Participants and landfill<br />

form a joint venture, both provide investment<br />

capital, and both share in the risks and<br />

rewards.<br />

Brokers—Match up interested buyers with<br />

sellers of the GHG credits generated under a<br />

landfill project for a fee.<br />

The amount of risk a landfill wants to assume (including<br />

the amount of capital it wants to put at risk) will<br />

determine what structure is most attractive.<br />

While the OTC market is highly flexible, it also lacks<br />

standardization and interchangeability. Multiple<br />

standards (protocols) are used, creating different<br />

project eligibility requirements, monitoring and<br />

validation requirements, and unique values for VERs<br />

from a particular standard and project type.<br />

The most commonly used standards or protocols in the<br />

OTC market include:<br />

Voluntary Carbon Standard 2007<br />

California Climate Action Registry<br />

GE-AES Greenhouse Gas Services<br />

USEPA Climate Leaders<br />

Environmental Resources Trust<br />

A landfill considering the OTC voluntary markets to<br />

sell its GHG reduction credits may want to consider<br />

the following advantages and disadvantages:<br />

8<br />

Advantages<br />

Flexible, relatively easy due diligence and<br />

verification process.<br />

Generally higher prices paid for tonnes of<br />

CO2e when compared to CCX,<br />

particularly for landfill methane reduction<br />

projects.<br />

Low transaction costs.<br />

No requirements of seller to reduce GHG<br />

emissions footprint.<br />

Can sell GHG credits forward.<br />

Carbon Asset Developers will provide<br />

investment capital.<br />

Disadvantages<br />

Lack of transparency of the OTC market<br />

transactions. No clear market price.<br />

Lack of standardization, leading to unique<br />

GHG credits (VERs) and pricing..<br />

Cannot usually sell older GHG credit<br />

vintages.<br />

Because OTC Market Participants are<br />

highly sophisticated, public entities may<br />

require outside assistance and a more<br />

diligent review.<br />

Pubic entities may require a pubic RFP<br />

process.<br />

Prices for GHG Credits<br />

The CCX has CFI® pricing history available. From an<br />

average price in 2006 of $3.50, prices fell to an<br />

average of $3.00 for 2007, with a price of only $1.60<br />

at the end of 2007. Since February of 2008, the price<br />

of CFI®s have increased sharply, driven by significant<br />

market volume. As this article goes to press, the value<br />

of a CFI® on CCX is $6.40.<br />

The OTC market transaction information is far less<br />

available, as most transaction details are not made<br />

public. The 2006 volume weighted average price for<br />

VERs in the OTC market was $4.1 per tonne CO2e,<br />

ranging widely from $0.45 to $45 per tonne CO2e.<br />

The highest prices paid were for high quality projects<br />

with verifiable attributes, such as landfill and coal mine<br />

methane based GHG reduction projects. K. Hamilton,<br />

R. Bayon, G. Turner, D. Higgins, “State of the<br />

Voluntary Carbon Markets 2007: Picking up Steam.”


Landfill Gas to Energy Considerations<br />

Some Landfill GHG Reduction Projects may have the<br />

additional possibility of incorporating a landfill gas-toenergy<br />

(LFGE) project, such as a LFG-fired electric<br />

generation project or a LFG direct use project (e.g.<br />

fire boilers). Both of these projects are, for most<br />

standards, approved methods of methane destruction<br />

and are thus eligible to generate GHG credits. The<br />

additional revenues generated from GHG credits can<br />

make borderline LFGE projects successful. With<br />

regard to electricity generation, additional GHG credits<br />

can be earned for the displacement of more carbon<br />

intense forms of electricity generation. The conditions<br />

under which Renewable Energy Credits (RECs) and<br />

GHG credits can be taken is beyond he scope of this<br />

article, but should be carefully addressed during<br />

negotiations to avoid double counting.<br />

Conclusions<br />

Smaller landfills now find themselves at the epicenter of<br />

interest surrounding climate change and specifically<br />

how voluntary control of LFG can contribute to GHG<br />

reductions. These publicly and privately held landfills<br />

have several project development options. Lawyers<br />

advising landfill clients would be well advised to<br />

become familiar with this emerging market.<br />

My colleague Jim Michelsen contributed to this<br />

article, which is based upon a paper he presented<br />

at the Solid <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Association</strong> of North America<br />

(SWANA) LFG Symposium in Houston earlier this<br />

year.<br />

COMMITTEE COMMITTEE ONLINE<br />

ONLINE<br />

Visit the <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong><br />

Web page at: www.abanet.org/environ/<br />

committees/solidwaste/.<br />

Back issues of the newsletter can be found<br />

at: http://www.abanet.org/environ/committees/solidwaste/newsletter/archives/.<br />

9<br />

Introduction<br />

WASTE DISPOSAL OF<br />

ELECTRONIC EQUIPMENT<br />

Heather Drayton<br />

J.D., Hofstra Law School<br />

Technological innovation continues to decrease the<br />

lifespan of electronics, resulting in an increase in the<br />

quantity of electronic waste, which is now the nation’s<br />

fastest growing category of solid waste, growing at a<br />

rate three times that of other usual municipal wastes.<br />

Significantly, regulatory mandates unrelated to<br />

environmental matters will increase the volume of<br />

electronic waste. For instance, the Federal<br />

Communications Commission (FCC) requires all new<br />

televisions to be equipped with technology for<br />

receiving digital signals. This phase out will result in<br />

500 million outdated devices that likely will be<br />

disposed in a landfill or recycled. In addition,<br />

according to Greenpeace, Microsoft’s launch of the<br />

Windows Vista operating system will render over half<br />

of the world’s computers obsolete because they will<br />

not have the basic system requirements to operate<br />

Vista.<br />

<strong>American</strong>s recycle only ten to fifteen percent of their<br />

electronic waste. The small proportion of consumers<br />

that do recycle endure inconvenient drop off locations<br />

and recycler disposal fees.<br />

Recycling electronic waste may be profitable overseas,<br />

where labor is inexpensive partially due to lack of<br />

environmental and worker safety regulations. However,<br />

entering the recycling market is cost prohibitive in the<br />

United States. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA)<br />

officials estimate the value of materials recovered is<br />

between $1 and $2.50 while the cost to recycle a<br />

desktop computer is about $15. As a result, recyclers<br />

may well choose to send electronic product overseas<br />

for disassembly and processing, both labor intensive<br />

undertakings. Eventually, disassembled parts may find<br />

their way back into the United States in undesirable<br />

forms. A study at Ohio’s Ashland University found that<br />

lead-containing electronic waste is finding its way into<br />

consumer products such as children’s toys made in<br />

China.


This article discusses regulatory approaches for dealing<br />

with the problematic issue of electronic waste recycling<br />

and disposal.<br />

Federal Electronic <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Scheme<br />

Current Federal Approach: Product<br />

Stewardship<br />

Federal regulations do not adequately address<br />

electronic waste disposal. The Resource Conservation<br />

Recovery Act (RCRA) regulates disposal of hazardous<br />

substances, but RCRA’s exceptions usually do not<br />

regulate electronic waste. Rather, RCRA allows likely<br />

electronic waste disposers (small quantity generators<br />

and household waste producers) to escape regulation.<br />

40 C.F.R. § 261.4(b)(1) (2006) (household waste<br />

exclusion); 40 C.F.R. § 261.5(f) (2006) (CESQG). 71<br />

Fed. Reg. 42,928, 42,928-29 (July 28, 2006)<br />

(codified at 40 C.F.R. pts. 9, 260, 261, 271) (cathode<br />

ray tubes and broken cathode ray tubes exclusion).<br />

Even if RCRA did apply to households and small<br />

quantity generators, the implementation and monitoring<br />

costs of applying RCRA to electronic waste may be<br />

overly burdensome and cost prohibitive to the<br />

administration. Keeping RCRA regulations at a<br />

manageable standard was Congress’s and the EPA’s<br />

intent when carving out these exceptions to the Act.<br />

The concept of product stewardship is a voluntary<br />

system utilized by the federal government regarding<br />

electronic waste disposal. Product stewardship occurs<br />

when responsibility for product disposal is shared by<br />

customers, retailers, product manufacturers, local<br />

governments, and volunteer organizations. EPA has<br />

developed several voluntary programs, such as<br />

Electronic Product Environmental Assessment Tool<br />

(EPEAT) for manufacturers. EPEAT rating lists<br />

products by performance level, including bronze, silver,<br />

or gold, based on twenty-three criteria including the<br />

reduction of lead, cadmium, and mercury; design for<br />

end-of-life and end-of-life management; life-cycle<br />

extension; energy conservation; corporate<br />

performance; and packaging. President Bush has<br />

signed executive orders that require federal agencies to<br />

utilize EPEAT when purchasing electronic equipment.<br />

10<br />

Congressional bills have been introduced to deal with<br />

these issues. The National Computer Recycling Act<br />

would permit the government to fund grants (through<br />

fees on new computers) to develop electronic waste<br />

recycling programs. Additionally, United States<br />

Senator Ron Wyden (D-Or.) and former Senator Jim<br />

Talent (R-Mo.) introduced S. 510, a bill aimed at<br />

encouraging nationwide electronic waste recycling.<br />

S. 510 would give tax credits to both consumers and<br />

manufactures for recycling electronic waste.<br />

The Patchwork Problem<br />

In the absence of a federally mandated solution to the<br />

electronic waste disposal problem, states are left to<br />

formulate regulations. Industry would prefer a national<br />

regulation rather than the many different state<br />

regulations that are emerging. The patchwork of<br />

policies and their inconsistencies from state to state<br />

create onerous compliance costs. In some cases, it is a<br />

difficult burden to comply with the extreme variations<br />

of the regulations. When faced with two different<br />

standards, manufacturers must comply with both, not<br />

just the stricter standard. Manufacturers may not only<br />

have to comply with the different state programs, but<br />

with different city and county electronic waste disposal<br />

schemes as well. Last year in the United States, fiftyfour<br />

electronic waste bills were proposed, and sixty<br />

were proposed in 2005. One-third of these bills<br />

charged the manufacturer or retailer with the duty to<br />

recycle the electronic waste, and another 15 percent<br />

were electronic waste landfill bans. The transaction<br />

costs of complying with all of these different regulations<br />

can have dramatic effects on the electronics<br />

manufactures, retailers, and the United States<br />

economy.<br />

Specific State Electronic <strong>Waste</strong> Regulations<br />

Some states have developed legislative approaches to<br />

deal with the issues. Thirteen states have some form of<br />

electronic waste regulation, and several have electronic<br />

waste regulations pending. The states that have<br />

enacted legislation are Arkansas, California,<br />

Connecticut, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts,<br />

Minnesota, New Hampshire, North Carolina, Oregon,<br />

Rhode Island, Texas, and Washington. Representatives


from Maine and California recently told Congress that,<br />

although those states already have electronic waste<br />

laws, “they could benefit from national leadership.”<br />

This article briefly examine the regulatory approaches<br />

of those two states.<br />

Maine<br />

Maine has a system modeled after the European Union<br />

(EU) approach called Extended Producer<br />

Responsibility (EPR), which requires the manufactures<br />

to pay for electronics recycling costs. The Maine law<br />

represents a partnership between the private sector,<br />

municipal and state entities, and consumers. The state<br />

requires manufacturers to ensure the recycling of their<br />

products. “[L]ocal government is responsible for<br />

collecting the waste equipment; and retailers are<br />

responsible for not selling products of manufacturers<br />

that fail to comply with the program.” The<br />

manufacturer is accountable for the costs of waste<br />

consolidators and processors for all of its electronics<br />

sold in Maine. Manufacturers are also likely<br />

responsible for electronic waste disposal of the<br />

residents of nearby states. There is nothing stopping<br />

non-residents from entering Maine to dispose of their<br />

electronic waste at a reduced cost.<br />

Electronic users in Maine benefit from this EPR<br />

approach. The consumer who used to pay $20 to<br />

recycle his computer prior to the regulation now pays<br />

only $2. However, manufacturers and retailers may be<br />

economically burdened. The electronic waste provision<br />

prohibits the sale of electronics by retailers or<br />

manufacturers not in compliance with regulations in<br />

Maine. If sales in Maine are not sufficient to cover the<br />

costs of disposal, this could take companies out of the<br />

Maine electronics market.<br />

Moreover, the statute will force some manufacturers to<br />

leave the Maine market. Manufactures not in<br />

compliance with the law after January 2006 are placed<br />

on a “do not sell list.” Maine retailers are prohibited<br />

(under penalty of law) from selling products made by<br />

non-compliant manufacturers. The threat to place<br />

manufacturers on a “do not sell list” is not an idle one.<br />

As of November 2007, Maine retailers cannot sell<br />

11<br />

electronic products from thirty non-compliant<br />

manufacturers.<br />

Other criticisms of Maine’s program target its so-called<br />

“orphan waste” requirement. “Orphan waste” is<br />

defined by statute as electronic devices where the<br />

manufacturer either “can not be identified or is no<br />

longer in business and has no successor in interest.”<br />

Manufacturers must implement and finance a plan both<br />

for the materials that they produce and for “orphan<br />

waste.” Cost of disposal for orphan units is divided<br />

between manufacturers based on a market share<br />

theory. Sorting waste to calculate manufacturer<br />

responsibility is complicated and creates a significant<br />

burden. This will almost certainly add to the “orphan<br />

waste” disposal costs.<br />

California<br />

Unlike Maine, which focuses its regulation on the<br />

producer, California utilizes an Advanced Recovery<br />

Fee (ARF), which focuses on consumers of<br />

electronics. California’s Electronic <strong>Waste</strong> Recycling<br />

Act of 2003 (EWRA) requires the consumer to pay a<br />

disposal and/or recycling cost at the time they purchase<br />

a covered electronic product. EWRA also requires<br />

state agencies to buy environmentally friendly<br />

electronics. Manufacturers evaluate the costs and<br />

benefits of selling environmentally conscious electronic<br />

products. Based on these considerations, the<br />

manufacturers provide agencies with recommendations<br />

for setting the criteria used in choosing approved<br />

electronics.<br />

The legislature addressed economic goals “to ensure<br />

that any cost associated with the proper management<br />

of covered electronic devices be internalized by the<br />

producers and consumers of covered electronic<br />

devices at or before the point of purchase, and not at<br />

the point of discard.” The legislature further states that<br />

in exchange for the benefit of the convenience of<br />

clearing their homes of electronic waste customers will<br />

pay $6 to $10 more at the time of purchase.<br />

EWRA opponents disagree with the California<br />

legislature. The upfront fee paid by the consumer takes<br />

away the manufacturer’s responsibility for electronic


waste disposal and shifts it to the government. This<br />

shift creates more government administrative burdens<br />

and reduces the incentive for manufacturers to<br />

implement design changes.<br />

The California Manufacturers and Technology<br />

<strong>Association</strong>, with some credibility, has called the<br />

provision a “job killer.” They fear economic effects will<br />

be so severe that jobs will be negatively affected.<br />

Consumers who want to avoid the California surcharge<br />

can find other places to purchase their computers (such<br />

as neighboring states) or delay or forgo purchase. Thus<br />

ARF starts a chain reaction beginning with decreasing<br />

computer sales which eventually leads to hindering<br />

California’s economy. The California Chamber of<br />

Commerce believes that not only is ARF bad for<br />

consumers, but it puts manufacturers at a disadvantage<br />

with nearby states. California retailers will lose profits if<br />

citizens can purchase electronics online and avoid the<br />

fee. This profit loss could inflict severe damage on<br />

California’s economy.<br />

The economic consequences of California’s ARF<br />

regulation are not all negative. The electronic recycling<br />

business in the area is booming. The biggest recycler in<br />

the state realized over $20 million in revenue in 2006.<br />

In addition to the state payment the recycler receives,<br />

he also gains revenue from the materials sold from the<br />

devices. California paid out $74.6 million in 2005 and<br />

2006 to electronic waste recyclers. This has attracted<br />

additional electronic waste disposal businesses,<br />

suggesting that those already in the industry may be<br />

earning supernormal profits (i.e., a return on capital<br />

greater than what is available in other industries). Since<br />

the implementation of EWRA, the number of recyclers<br />

and collectors has nearly tripled, thereby increasing<br />

competition. To keep profits up despite all of the<br />

competition, collectors hold recycling events to gather<br />

electronic waste. These events lower the transaction<br />

costs to consumers by creating more convenient drop<br />

off locations. When transaction costs are lowered the<br />

consumer is more likely to remove the product from<br />

storage and bring it to the event. Thus, the recyclers<br />

gain revenue.<br />

12<br />

Conclusion<br />

Consumers are going to continue disposing of their<br />

electronic waste using the method least costly to them.<br />

In order to encourage recycling and reuse, landfill bans<br />

should be imposed and a financing system should be<br />

developed to encourage recycling.<br />

Economic analysis indicates that all stakeholders,<br />

including government and industry, should collaborate<br />

to develop an environmentally responsible and<br />

economically efficient plan. To avoid the economic<br />

waste that a patchwork system creates, the federal<br />

government should implement an appropriate financing<br />

system. The negotiations should consider the pros and<br />

cons of the approaches used by various states to date.<br />

Ideally, the most efficient regulation will protect the<br />

environment while allowing businesses to operate<br />

profitably within the United States.<br />

Heather Drayton was graduated in May 2008 from<br />

Hofstra Law School.<br />

This article is adapted from “Economic Analysis of<br />

Electronic <strong>Waste</strong> Disposal Regulations,” published in<br />

36 Hofstra Law Review, 149 (2007). For citations<br />

please refer to the original publication available at<br />

http://law.hofstra.edu/pdf/Academics/Journals/<br />

LawReview/lrv_issues_v36n01_i07.pdf.<br />

LIKE LIKE LIKE TO O WRITE? WRITE?<br />

WRITE?<br />

The <strong>Waste</strong> <strong>Management</strong> <strong>Committee</strong><br />

welcomes the participation of members<br />

who are interested in preparing this<br />

newsletter.<br />

If you would like to lend a hand by writing,<br />

editing, identifying authors, or identifying<br />

issues, please contact Theodore Hadzi-<br />

Antich or Andrew M. Kenefick.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!