31.07.2013 Views

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

78 Chapter 4<br />

Hughes’ basic model of <strong>change</strong> of large technical systems focuses on two<br />

main dimensions. The first involves <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong> system interacts with<br />

external or contextual <strong>change</strong>s <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> second <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong> system solves<br />

internal problems that hampers system expansion. These reverse salients, as<br />

Hughes labelled <strong>the</strong>m, can be solved if ac<strong>to</strong>rs collectively perceive a specific<br />

problem as <strong>the</strong> major bottleneck <strong>and</strong> if <strong>the</strong>ir activities are mobilised in<br />

overcoming this reverse salient. Ac<strong>to</strong>rs with a leading role within <strong>the</strong> system,<br />

such as a system builder as Edison, may be able <strong>to</strong> translate reverse salients<br />

in<strong>to</strong> critical problems that become shared by o<strong>the</strong>r ac<strong>to</strong>rs, while boundary<br />

spanners such as Insull play an important part in <strong>the</strong> diffusion of <strong>the</strong>se ideas.<br />

Apart from <strong>the</strong> more technical <strong>and</strong> legal principles listed above it is thus<br />

possible <strong>to</strong> add ano<strong>the</strong>r, more cognitive, principle of sharing similar ideas<br />

about <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> problems within <strong>the</strong> system <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>y should<br />

be solved.<br />

Verbong et al. (2000) account of <strong>the</strong> evolution of <strong>the</strong> Dutch electricity<br />

system shows how Dutch municipalities <strong>and</strong> provinces streng<strong>the</strong>ned <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

grip on electricity supply by opening public facilities <strong>and</strong> refusing<br />

concessions <strong>to</strong> private companies. This process ran parallel with increasing<br />

economies of scale made possible as investments in steam turbine outran<br />

steam engines <strong>and</strong> as alternating current was increasingly adopted for larger<br />

distribution networks. Electricity supply thus increasingly <strong>to</strong>ok <strong>the</strong> form of a<br />

natural monopoly <strong>and</strong> was dominated by initially municipal <strong>and</strong> later<br />

provincial stakeholders.<br />

The way in which electricity consumption developed <strong>and</strong> was cultivated is<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r crucial part of <strong>the</strong> <strong>transition</strong> <strong>to</strong>wards an electricity system.<br />

Households had <strong>to</strong> become used <strong>to</strong> electric lamps, a ra<strong>the</strong>r different practice<br />

than using oil or gas lamps, although generally quickly considered more<br />

convenient due <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> invention of <strong>the</strong> inc<strong>and</strong>escent light bulb by Edison in<br />

1879. Electric trams replaced horse trams, <strong>and</strong> manufacturing companies<br />

shifted from steam <strong>and</strong> water engines <strong>to</strong> electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs as <strong>the</strong>ir source for<br />

mechanical drive. In an analysis of <strong>the</strong> shift from steam <strong>to</strong> electric power in<br />

US manufacturing Devine (1983) reports how initially electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs were<br />

used <strong>to</strong> replace steam engines without <strong>change</strong>s in <strong>the</strong> organisation of<br />

production. At <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> 19th century steam engines were <strong>the</strong> main<br />

source for mechanically powering machines. The first use of electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs<br />

in manufacturing plants was in 1884, in 1900 <strong>the</strong> share of electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs as<br />

a source for mechanical drive was about 3%, in 1910 around 20%, in 1920<br />

over 50% with electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs replacing steam engines as <strong>the</strong> main source<br />

for mechanical drive, <strong>and</strong> in 1929 78% of <strong>to</strong>tal capacity for mechanical drive<br />

was based on electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs (Devine, 1983: 349). At first instance<br />

substitution <strong>to</strong>ok only place in those cases where replacing steam engines by<br />

electric mo<strong>to</strong>rs for driving machinery reduced direct costs. As companies

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!