31.07.2013 Views

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Analytical framework 67<br />

of doing things is taken-for-granted <strong>and</strong> embedded in regulative <strong>and</strong><br />

normative institutions. An example is <strong>the</strong> way every house in <strong>the</strong><br />

Ne<strong>the</strong>rl<strong>and</strong>s is connected <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> electricity grid, <strong>and</strong> provided with electricity<br />

sockets. This is taken-for-granted by both house owners as those involved in<br />

planning <strong>and</strong> building houses. But, as we will show in <strong>the</strong> coming chapter,<br />

this was not taken for granted in <strong>the</strong> early 1900s. Through a process of<br />

normative (societal goal of access <strong>to</strong> electricity for everyone) <strong>and</strong> regulative<br />

(withholding concessions if not everyone was <strong>to</strong> be connected) institution<br />

building every household became connected, <strong>and</strong> electricity became takenfor-granted.<br />

Important is <strong>the</strong> realisation that this process of<br />

<strong>institutional</strong>isation could be successful because it had acquired legitimacy<br />

within society (convenience <strong>and</strong> low cost of electricity), within government<br />

(electricity growth as a means for economic growth), <strong>and</strong> within <strong>the</strong><br />

economy (electricity as effective <strong>and</strong> low-cost power source).<br />

Our focus is especially on <strong>the</strong> interplay between <strong>change</strong>s in practices<br />

(innovations) <strong>and</strong> <strong>institutional</strong> <strong>change</strong>s. A main premise is that <strong>change</strong>s in<br />

practices can only become durable <strong>and</strong> significant (in <strong>the</strong> sense of<br />

representing a form of systems <strong>change</strong>) if <strong>the</strong>y are accompanied by<br />

<strong>institutional</strong> <strong>change</strong>s that act as carriers of <strong>the</strong> new practices. Simply stated:<br />

innovation <strong>and</strong> <strong>institutional</strong> <strong>change</strong> are two sides of <strong>the</strong> same coin of systems<br />

<strong>change</strong>. With regard <strong>to</strong> institutions we use <strong>the</strong> idea of a hierarchy. This<br />

implies some kind of nested system of sets of practices guided by sets of<br />

institutions, <strong>and</strong> activities aimed <strong>to</strong> <strong>change</strong> those institutions, such as<br />

proposed by Holm (1995). We feel this distinction is valuable, because it<br />

represents two <strong>to</strong>tally different playing fields, comparable <strong>to</strong> playing chess at<br />

<strong>the</strong> chessboard on <strong>the</strong> one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> trying <strong>to</strong> <strong>change</strong> <strong>the</strong> rules for chess<br />

within a rule-making body such as <strong>the</strong> FIDE 2 at <strong>the</strong> same time. Apart from<br />

discerning between practices guided by institutions <strong>and</strong> practices intended <strong>to</strong><br />

manipulate institutions, we also distinguish institutions that represent ground<br />

rules (or fundamental rules) <strong>and</strong> specification rules that specify, <strong>and</strong> built<br />

upon, ground rules, inspired by, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, Coriat <strong>and</strong> Weinstein (2002).<br />

Creating a level playing field within European electricity systems in <strong>the</strong><br />

wave of liberalisation in <strong>the</strong> 1990s <strong>and</strong> 2000s may be considered a ground<br />

rule, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rules under which mergers may exceed acceptable levels of<br />

market shares in defined areas as a specification rule.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, we contend that dominant practices organised in sociotechnical<br />

systems gain stability as a certain ‘<strong>institutional</strong> logics’ becomes prevalent. In<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r words: a particular <strong>institutional</strong> logics shapes practices, ex<strong>change</strong><br />

relationships, <strong>and</strong> structures. We define <strong>institutional</strong> logics as a set of<br />

socially constructed assumptions, values, <strong>and</strong> beliefs (Sine <strong>and</strong> David, 2003:<br />

2 International Chess Federation.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!