31.07.2013 Views

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Theoretical perspectives 19<br />

Nelson <strong>and</strong> Winter (1982) developed an evolutionary <strong>the</strong>ory of economic<br />

<strong>change</strong> with routines as principal elements <strong>to</strong> explain firm behaviour. In<br />

evolutionary economics, habits <strong>and</strong> routines function as relatively durable<br />

genes, because “firms may be expected <strong>to</strong> behave in <strong>the</strong> future according <strong>to</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> routines <strong>the</strong>y have employed in <strong>the</strong> past” (Nelson <strong>and</strong> Winter, 1982:<br />

134). Routines are defined as decision-rules that are applied routinely over<br />

longer periods of time, <strong>and</strong> “range from well-specified technical routines for<br />

producing things, procedures for hiring <strong>and</strong> firing, ordering new inven<strong>to</strong>ry,<br />

or stepping up production of items in high dem<strong>and</strong>, <strong>to</strong> policies regarding<br />

investment, research <strong>and</strong> development, or advertising, <strong>and</strong> business<br />

strategies about product diversification <strong>and</strong> overseas investments” (Nelson<br />

<strong>and</strong> Winter, 1982: 14). Routines are ‘remembered’ by doing, just as<br />

professional piano- or tennis-players need <strong>to</strong> practice every day <strong>to</strong> keep <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

movements smooth <strong>and</strong> accurate, in a natural <strong>and</strong> unconscious way. This<br />

also implies that <strong>the</strong>re is some level of tacitness involved: routines can not be<br />

transferred smoothly, just as skills need <strong>to</strong> be built up. Nelson <strong>and</strong> Winter<br />

(1982: 16-17) discern three types of routines within firms, those of an<br />

operational nature, those regarding investment decisions, <strong>and</strong> routines <strong>to</strong><br />

modify various operating characteristics, thus contemplating whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

way <strong>the</strong>y are doing things is still appropriate. Here <strong>the</strong>y assume a hierarchy<br />

of decision rules with higher order procedures governing modification of<br />

lower ones. In <strong>the</strong> economy <strong>the</strong> most successful routines survive (are<br />

selected) <strong>and</strong> are transferred <strong>to</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r firms through imitation, take-overs,<br />

labour mobility <strong>and</strong> training. According <strong>to</strong> Nelson <strong>and</strong> Winter routines also<br />

play a crucial role in innovative activities. They view innovations in<br />

organisational routines as new combinations of existing routines. They argue<br />

that problem-solving is routinised in terms of <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong> problem is<br />

approached: certain search <strong>and</strong> problem-solving heuristics are applied<br />

(Nelson <strong>and</strong> Winter, 1982: 132-133). Search processes are local in <strong>the</strong> sense<br />

that <strong>the</strong> focus is on techniques close <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong> current one (Nelson <strong>and</strong> Winter,<br />

1982: 211). This leads <strong>to</strong> technological trajec<strong>to</strong>ries based on general<br />

principles on how <strong>to</strong> move a certain technology, technological configuration<br />

or system forward. Saviotti (1996: 45) argues that “know-how, routines,<br />

decision rules <strong>and</strong> dominant competences are relatively invariant with<br />

respect <strong>to</strong> many types of environmental <strong>change</strong>s thus giving rise <strong>to</strong> dominant<br />

designs, technological regimes <strong>and</strong> paradigms”. Dosi (1988: 225) uses <strong>the</strong><br />

term technological paradigm that defines “<strong>the</strong> technological opportunities<br />

for fur<strong>the</strong>r innovations <strong>and</strong> some basic procedures on how <strong>to</strong> exploit <strong>the</strong>m”.<br />

Certain exemplars (basic artefacts such as a car, steam turbine or fuel cell)<br />

are fur<strong>the</strong>r developed <strong>and</strong> improved on <strong>the</strong> basis of a set of heuristics that<br />

guide direction <strong>and</strong> knowledge nature of search processes (Dosi, 1988: 224).<br />

An example is <strong>the</strong> steam turbine for which efficiency steadily improved by

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!