31.07.2013 Views

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

Innovation and institutional change: the transition to a sustainable ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

176 Chapter 6<br />

After <strong>the</strong> opening of <strong>the</strong> Dutch retail market for green electricity in July<br />

2001 <strong>the</strong> number of green electricity cus<strong>to</strong>mers increased from about<br />

250,000 <strong>to</strong> approximately 800,000 early 2002 <strong>and</strong> 1.4 million in January<br />

2003. The sharp increase was caused by aggressive marketing campaigns for<br />

green electricity cus<strong>to</strong>mers, pricing strategies that even led <strong>to</strong> green<br />

electricity offered below <strong>the</strong> price of conventional electricity (made possible<br />

by <strong>the</strong> favourable fiscal measures for green electricity), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> focus on<br />

green electricity as a <strong>to</strong>ol for energy companies <strong>to</strong> attract new cus<strong>to</strong>mers <strong>and</strong><br />

establish <strong>the</strong>ir retail br<strong>and</strong> in anticipation of full liberalisation of <strong>the</strong><br />

electricity market.<br />

Support system dismantled due <strong>to</strong> opening up of green electricity market<br />

Liberalisation of <strong>the</strong> market for green electricity also generated a not<br />

intended side-effect. The attractive compensation for green electricity, which<br />

consisted of restitution of <strong>the</strong> regula<strong>to</strong>ry energy tax <strong>and</strong> a producer<br />

compensation for renewable electricity, <strong>the</strong> strong rise in cus<strong>to</strong>mer dem<strong>and</strong><br />

for green electricity <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> difficulty of initiating domestic renewable<br />

electricity facilities led domestic producers <strong>to</strong> increasingly import renewable<br />

electricity 23 . Also foreign energy providers started <strong>to</strong> offer green electricity<br />

<strong>to</strong> Dutch cus<strong>to</strong>mers as from 2002 on renewable electricity exported <strong>to</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Ne<strong>the</strong>rl<strong>and</strong>s could qualify for <strong>the</strong> green certificate scheme <strong>and</strong> consequently<br />

become eligible for exemption from <strong>the</strong> regula<strong>to</strong>ry energy tax. The result<br />

was that <strong>the</strong> growth in dem<strong>and</strong> for green electricity after liberalisation was<br />

mainly satisfied by green electricity of already existing installations for<br />

renewable electricity generation, especially hydropower <strong>and</strong> biomass<br />

facilities (Kroon, 2002: 26; Reijnders, 2002). Differences in support schemes<br />

for renewable energy around Europe contributed <strong>to</strong> this, with only in <strong>the</strong><br />

Ne<strong>the</strong>rl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>the</strong> support system was mainly based on fiscal measures,<br />

whereas in most European countries <strong>the</strong> main schemes were supply oriented<br />

feed-in tariffs or dem<strong>and</strong> oriented quota obligation or renewable portfolio<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards (van Sambeek <strong>and</strong> van Thuijl, 2003). Although <strong>the</strong> threat of<br />

companies exploiting <strong>the</strong> mismatch between different policy frameworks<br />

was pointed out early (Boots et al., 2001), <strong>the</strong> strong rise in imports was not<br />

anticipated by Dutch government. Public <strong>and</strong> political discussion regarding<br />

<strong>the</strong> leakage of tax money through imported green electricity led <strong>to</strong><br />

abolishment of <strong>the</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>-oriented fiscal scheme in 2003. The system was<br />

replaced by subsidies for <strong>the</strong> electricity generated from facilities using<br />

23 If specific contracts were made with foreign suppliers regarding renewable electricity, this<br />

contracted electricity was also eligible for <strong>the</strong> exemption of <strong>the</strong> regula<strong>to</strong>ry energy tax <strong>and</strong><br />

production subsidies could be received. Provisions in <strong>the</strong> Green Tax Act (WBM in Dutch)<br />

prohibited making distinction between renewable production in <strong>and</strong> outside <strong>the</strong><br />

Ne<strong>the</strong>rl<strong>and</strong>s (Kroon, 2002: 10).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!