20.07.2013 Views

e - Mass Cases

e - Mass Cases

e - Mass Cases

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

Page<br />

STATEMENT OF THE ISSUES .............................. 1<br />

STATEMENT OF THE CASE ................................ 1<br />

STATEMENT OF FACTS ................................... 5<br />

SUMMARY OF THE ARGW MENT .............................. 8<br />

ARG~~ENT ............................................ 10<br />

I. Keyspan's appeal never addresses<br />

the proper legal Issue in this<br />

case ...................................... 10<br />

11. Keyspan has extraordinary evidentiary<br />

burdens since all of ita challenges are<br />

to matters entrusted to the Board.........lz<br />

111. The Board addressed this case<br />

precisely as Watertown requires ........... 14<br />

IV. The AsseSSOrs met their watertom burden..l5<br />

A. The Assessors provided substantial<br />

evidence that utility property sells<br />

for greater than its net book cost ... 15<br />

E. Keyspan failed to rebut the<br />

Assessors' sales evidence at<br />

trial and cannot establish that<br />

the Board lacked substantial.<br />

evidence for its findings ............ 24<br />

i. Keyspan had no affirmative<br />

evidence showing that utility<br />

property only sells for its net<br />

book cost ....................... 25<br />

1


ii. Keyspan had no evidence showing<br />

that the sales premiums were<br />

paid for other than utility<br />

propcrty ........................ 27<br />

...<br />

111. Neither the seller's existing<br />

rates nor expenses determine<br />

what will be paid to buy the<br />

property ........................ 32<br />

C. Substantial changes in regulatory<br />

po1.icy permit sales at more than<br />

net book cost ........................ 36<br />

V. With Watertown rebutted Keyspan had the<br />

burden of overcoming the presumptive<br />

validity of the assessments ............... 41<br />

VI. Keyspan's other criticisms are<br />

irrelevant, immaterial and largely<br />

incorrect ................................. 43<br />

VII. Because Keyspan also failed to meet its<br />

burden on the real property the Board<br />

properly affirmed the assessment .......... 48<br />

CONCLUSION .......................................... 49


TABLE OF AUTHORITIES<br />

MASSACHUSETTS CASES<br />

Analogic Corp. v. Board of Assessors of Peabody<br />

45 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Ct. GO5 (1998) ........................ 35<br />

Attorney General v.<br />

Department af Telecommunications and Energy<br />

438 <strong>Mass</strong>. 256 (2002 ............................. 38.39<br />

Attorncy General v.<br />

215 <strong>Mass</strong>. 394 (1913<br />

Haverhill Gas Light: Co.<br />

................................ 31<br />

Boston Edison C0.v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Boston<br />

402 MasE. 1. (1988) ............................ 10,13,14<br />

Boston Edison Co. v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Watertown<br />

387 <strong>Mass</strong>. 298 (1982) ............................p assim<br />

Boston Gas Co+ v. ASS~SSO~S of Boston<br />

331 <strong>Mass</strong>. 549 (1956) ............................. L3,35<br />

Boston Gas Co. v.<br />

Department of Telecommunications and Energy<br />

436 <strong>Mass</strong>. 233 (2002) ................................ 40<br />

Uehydratinq Process Po. v. City of GlOuCeSter<br />

334 <strong>Mass</strong>. 287 (1956) ................................ 48<br />

Eoxboro Associates v.<br />

Board US Assessors of Foxborough<br />

385 <strong>Mass</strong>. 679 (1982) ................................ 41<br />

General Electric Co. v.<br />

Roaxd of Assessors of Lynn<br />

333 <strong>Mass</strong>. 591 (1984) ............................. 11,46<br />

iii


Halampton Associates v.<br />

Board Of Assessors of Northampton<br />

52 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Ct. 110 (2001) ..... .. .42<br />

J.A. Schlaiker v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Great Barrington<br />

365 <strong>Mass</strong>. 243 (1974) .......................... 11,27,41<br />

<strong>Mass</strong>achusetts Institute oE Technology v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Cambridge<br />

422 <strong>Mass</strong>. 447 (1996).... ............................ 13<br />

Montaup Electric Co. v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Whitman<br />

390 <strong>Mass</strong>. 847 (1984) ....................... 14,15,42,49<br />

Olympia & York State St. Co. v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Boston<br />

428 <strong>Mass</strong>. 236 (1998) ................................ 14<br />

Peterson v. Board of ASSeSSOrS of Boston<br />

62 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Ct. 428 (2004) ........................ 35<br />

Pollard v. Conservation Commission of Norfolk<br />

73 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Ct. 340 (2008) ........................ 18<br />

Reliable Electronic Finishing Co.,Inc. v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Canton<br />

410 Mazx. 381 (1391) ................................ 42<br />

School. Committee of Boston v. Board of Education<br />

363 <strong>Mass</strong>. 125 (1973) ............................. 46-47<br />

Stow Municipal E.lec. Dep't. v.<br />

Department of Public Kltil.<br />

426 <strong>Mass</strong>. 341 (1997) . ...........................p assim<br />

Syms Corp. v. Commissioner of Revenue<br />

436 <strong>Mass</strong>. 505 (2002) ................................ 13<br />

Tennessee Gas Pipeline CO. v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Agawam<br />

428 <strong>Mass</strong>. 261 (1998) ......................... 13.14.15<br />

iV


APPELLATE TAX BOARD CASES<br />

Boston Edison Company v.<br />

Board of Assessors of the C ity of Everett<br />

20 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Tax Bd. Rep. 3 (1996) .............. 10,24<br />

STATUTES AND REGULATIONS<br />

G.L. c. 58A, § 13 ................................ 12,24<br />

G.L. c. 164, 5 96 ................................... 23<br />

G.L. c. 164, 5 21 ................................... 3~<br />

15 u.S.C. 5 79j (b)(2) ............................ 20,23<br />

DPU/DTE ORDERS<br />

DTE 99-19<br />

(,3oint. Petition of Boston Edison Pa.) .17.33<br />

DTE 03-40 ........................................ 38,40<br />

OTHER AUTHORITIES<br />

Appraisal Institute, The Appraisal of Real<br />

Estate (13‘” Ed. 2008) ............................... 35<br />

Phillips, The Regulation of Public Utilities<br />

ra<br />

(3 Ed. 1993) ........................................ 29,31<br />

V


STAT- OF THE 58SW8 -<br />

1. Whether the Board had substantial evidence for<br />

finding that market transactions confirm that buyers pay<br />

more than net book value ("net book") for utility property.<br />

2. whether the Board had substantial evidence for<br />

finding that changes in DPU policy make it possible that<br />

utility property would sell at greater than net book.<br />

3. Because the Assessors adequately rebutted any<br />

presumption that the property could only sell at net book,<br />

whether the Board's finding that Keyspan failed to meet its<br />

burden of demonstrating that its property wan overvalued<br />

was sufficient xeaaon to deny abatement.<br />

4. Whether the Board correctly found that Keyspan<br />

failed to meet its burden that its land was overvalued.<br />

STATEMENT OF THE CASE<br />

--"I___<br />

Appellant's discussion of the proceedings i s accurate<br />

but its recounting of the decision is incomplete and<br />

partially incorrect. It is incomplete because it omits any<br />

reference to the Appellate Tax Board's ("Board") actual<br />

disposition.<br />

The omission appears designed to permit<br />

Keyspan to cast this appeal as one in which picking at the<br />

minutia of expert's work or the Board's valuation<br />

methodology might change the result. Keyspan therefore


ecounts that the Board found net book "no longer a<br />

reliable indicator of value" and moves right on to<br />

discussing the property's value. Brief of Keyspan ("Brief")<br />

at 4. That description elides the essence of the decision.<br />

Keyspan rolled the dice that the analysis set out in<br />

Boston Edison Co. v. Board of ;4ssessors of Watertown, 387<br />

<strong>Mass</strong>. 298 (1382) ("Watertown") would require that the Board<br />

find the fair cash value of its property is net book. It<br />

elected a "single reliance on net book value as the<br />

determinant of fair cash value", but "relied primarily on<br />

theory.'' RA. 104. Its case "focused and was largely<br />

dependent on the testimony of" an economist who did little<br />

but put a face on the Watertom syllogism by providing<br />

testimony correctly characterized by the Board as simply<br />

repeating a "premise". RA. 16, 76. Its witnesses dutifully<br />

insisted that net book was always the property's worth but<br />

they neither offered actual evidence nor supported that<br />

with an appraiser who might temper their dogmatism with a<br />

more credible analysis. RA. 79, n.31, 80.<br />

The Board recognized that any relevance of net book<br />

cost to fair cash value now requires evidentiary support.<br />

It reached this conclusion in large part because it had<br />

been shown market transactions at prices hundreds of<br />

2


millions of dollars higher than they should have been had<br />

Keyspan's theory been correct. It had no trouble realizing<br />

chat Keyspan's attempts to explain these prices away<br />

similarly suffered from "lack of substantiation, which<br />

fundamentally undermined" Keyspan's case. RA. 23.<br />

The Board also found that since its last utility<br />

valuation case there had been a continued reorientation of<br />

DPU policy that made Keyspan's "single reliance"<br />

unsustainable. In consideration of these facts, the Board<br />

held that the Board of Assessors ("ASSe8SOrS") had<br />

satisfactorily met their burden and had successfully put<br />

the relevance of net book cost into question. RA. 103.<br />

Despite the clear import of that evidence Keyspan<br />

maintained its absolute but unsupported reliance on net<br />

book. The Board held that Keyspan had "failed to offer<br />

persuasive evidence of the fair cash value of the<br />

property," RA. 80, and ruled that it did not "sustain its<br />

burden of establishing that the property's value wan less<br />

than its asseased value for fiscal year 2004."<br />

RA.83,104.110. The Board therefore refused any abatement.<br />

This outcome is never once mentioned in Keyspan's<br />

brief which focuses instead on the Watertown findings and<br />

criticism of the Board's value calculations. Hawever, the<br />

3


a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

1,<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

*<br />

e<br />

0<br />

*<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e * e<br />

a<br />

Board's election to continue beyond its conclusion that<br />

Keyspan failed to meet its burden of proof, and to<br />

determine the value of the property, although helpful and<br />

comfortably supportive of the ultimate result, is legally<br />

redundant and renders irrelevant Keyspan's prospecting for<br />

flaws in valuation technique.<br />

Keyspan's description of the decision is also<br />

partially incorrect. It repeatedly contends that the Board<br />

found that "as a result" of a change in regulatory policy<br />

the "contemporaneous regulatory environment" explains sales<br />

of utility property above net book cost. Brief at 1, 4, 23.<br />

Yet what the Board actually found requires no causal<br />

explanation. Simply. it found there waa an active, vibrant<br />

market in the sale of utility property and sales data<br />

existed. No longer must utility valuation cases merely<br />

seek a "possible" answer to a hypothetical. question ("why a<br />

buyer would want to pay more than Edison's net book<br />

value..."). Watertom, 387 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 305.<br />

The Board's finding that the strict regulatory policy<br />

undergirding Watertown no longer existed was an independent<br />

basis for its conclusion that net book does not equate to<br />

value. The magnitude of the transactions in the market<br />

alone rebutted the watertom presumption. No matter the<br />

4


cause, the elephant in the room was documented sales of<br />

utility property at huge premiums over net book. The Board<br />

recognized that net book no longer drives value because<br />

both the cause and effect of the Watertown logic are<br />

obsolete.<br />

STATXMENT OF FACTS<br />

Because many of the facts relevant to the iasues in<br />

this appeal relate to transactions and regulatory policy<br />

there is no bright line between fact and legal analysis.<br />

Nor can many of the facts be usefully presented independent<br />

of some degree of argument ao they will not appear here.<br />

There are three sets of facts, however, of direct relevance<br />

to the Assessors' unique burden and which had primary<br />

importance in the outcome of the case. Keyspan's efforts,<br />

and failure, to convince the Board that these facts meant<br />

other than what they plainly do mean determined the course<br />

of the trial and dictated the result.<br />

The first fact is that utility property, including the<br />

property in this case, has consistently been bought at<br />

prices substantially more than its net book cost. RA. 3934-<br />

35. The sale of the Boston Gas property is typical.<br />

The taxable property at issue is owned by B08tOn Gas<br />

Company ("Boston Gas"). Until 2000, Boston Gas was wholly<br />

5


owned by Eastern Enterprises ("Eastern"). In November<br />

2000, Eastern was acquired by Keyspan Corporation<br />

("Keyspan") and in 2008 Keyspan was acquired by National<br />

Grid. PA. 7, 3832.<br />

The Keyspan acquisition of Eastern is a useful lens<br />

through which to see this case. It is one of the sales<br />

passed off by Keyspan as too complex and multifaceted to be<br />

capable of revealing useful data. In reality the Board was<br />

able to both examine it in fine detail and appreciate its<br />

significance in broad strokes.<br />

Three years before the tax dare for this case, Keyspan<br />

paid $1,754,415.231.84 for Eastern, a sum which exceeded<br />

the net book cost of EaSteTn'S assets by over a billion<br />

dollars. RA. 667,669. Eastern was comprised of three<br />

utility companies and a few unregulated businesses so<br />

Keyspan argues that nothing useful can be learned because<br />

information relevant to Boston Gas's taxable utility<br />

property is irretrievably buried beneath layers of<br />

corporations and enterprise attributes. Brief at 32; RA.<br />

3968.<br />

Keyspan records reflect, however, that the price it<br />

paid just for Boston Gas (net book of assets $271,008,000)<br />

was $1,021,320,749 "based on multiple of book value of<br />

6


e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

I)<br />

e<br />

a<br />

*<br />

e *<br />

a<br />

8<br />

e<br />

e<br />

I,<br />

0<br />

a<br />

8<br />

a<br />

m<br />

a<br />

a<br />

*<br />

a<br />

3.7686". RA. 668, Note "B" . That is an "acquisition<br />

premium" above the net book of the Boston Gas assets of<br />

$750,312,749.00.' This premium was paid €or "the utility<br />

operations of Boston Gas Company," RA. 3623 and, despite<br />

Keyspan's insistence it represents intangible value, was<br />

booked as "utility plant in service." RA. 3990, 1867.<br />

The second significant fact is that the "apparent<br />

policy" of the DPU which was the foundation for the<br />

Watertown case no longer exists. The Board traced its<br />

transformation since 1982 providing context, logic and<br />

detail. RA. 88-97. In reality the effort was more than was<br />

necessary since the simple, largely conceded, fact is the<br />

strict Watertown rationale was effectively laid to rest in<br />

1997 when the DPU analyzed the impact of its changed<br />

policies on valuing utility distribution property. Then<br />

the agency whose "carryover rate base" rule is the<br />

foundation of Keyspan's theory did exactly as the Board did<br />

here; it considered the impact of DPU regulation on the<br />

possible sale of utility distribution property and valued<br />

it at 50% depreciated reproduction cost ("RCNLD") and 50%<br />

' Accounting adjustments changed the numbers somewhat. In<br />

the Boston Gas rate case the Eastern premium was described<br />

as "approximately" $1.127 billion and the Boston Gas premium<br />

$812,950,019. RA. 2707.<br />

7


net book. It did this while specifically conducting the<br />

Watertown analysis but reached a different Outcome because<br />

its "recently changed" carryover rate base policy meant a<br />

buyer "should pay more than original cost less<br />

depreciation.'' This Court affirmed. Stow Municipal Elec.<br />

Dep't. v. Department of Public #til., 426 <strong>Mass</strong>. 341, 345-<br />

347 (1937) ("Stow").<br />

The third fact found significant by the Board is that<br />

the property at issue is no longer subject to strict cost<br />

based rates of the sort employed at the time of Watertown<br />

and necessary for i ts logic to prevail. In place of rates<br />

based exclusively on recovery of expended coats plus return<br />

on rate base there are now Performance BaSed Rates ("PBR").<br />

FA. 3952. Keyspan's witness, Dr. Tierney, agreed this is<br />

"a significant change in the rate making process €or<br />

regulated utilities in <strong>Mass</strong>achusetts." RA. 3668.<br />

aDbMAIcy OF THE ARQUMENT<br />

Keyspan's appeal never addresses the fact that it wa3<br />

found to have provided no evidence that the assessment8<br />

were in error and, as a result, they are presumed valid.<br />

Consequently, much of what Keyspan argues is irrelevant.<br />

(pp.10-12) It has also elected to appeal only factual<br />

8


findings, which are final, or matters committed to the<br />

judgment of the Board. (pp.12-14)<br />

The Board correctly analyzed the issues and found that<br />

the Asse8sors met their burden of putting the relevance of<br />

net book in doubt. First they provided evidence of sales<br />

of utility property at greater than net book cost. (pp.14-<br />

24) Keyspan failed to affirmatively show that utility<br />

property sale prices would be capped at net book cost<br />

lpp.25-27) OK rebut the significance of the sales premiums<br />

since it failed to convince the Board that the premiums<br />

were only for non-utility property or an "enterprise".<br />

(pp.27-36)<br />

The Board also properly found that DPU regulations<br />

concerning sale of utility property and the manner in which<br />

rates are set had substantially changed since 1982. (pp.<br />

36-41) With the Watertown presumptions rebutted, Keyspan<br />

reacquired, and failed to meet, the burden of proving any<br />

effect of regulation or that its property was otherwise<br />

overvalued. (pp.41-43) Even if Keyspan's valuation<br />

criticisms were relevant they are immaterial and, in any<br />

event, wrong, (pp. 44-45<br />

Board's refusal to abate<br />

(pp.48-49)<br />

including that directed at the<br />

the taxes on Commercial Point.<br />

9


AR0-E<br />

I. Keyspan's appeal never addresees the<br />

proper legal issue in this caae.<br />

The Board waa quite explicit in what it did and was<br />

thorough in explaining why. First, it found that the<br />

Assessors had met their burden under Watertown and had<br />

called the relevance of net book into question. RA. 100-<br />

103; see section 111 in€ra. Although the Board was<br />

*'particularly" convinced by the sale8 evidence, it also<br />

supported its conclusion with the changed regulatory<br />

environment. ThiE should hardly have come as a surprise to<br />

Keyspan since that trend began over 20 years ago in Boston<br />

Edison Co. v. Board of Assessors of Boston, 402 <strong>Mass</strong>. 1<br />

(1988). continued in Boston Eddison Company v. Board of<br />

Asses6ors of the City of Everett, 20 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Tax Bd.<br />

Rep. 3 (1996). and became indisputable in Stow where this<br />

Court both acknowledged that the policy underlying<br />

Watertown had changed and affirmed the DPU's conclusions<br />

about the effect of that change on value.<br />

Nevertheless, Keyspan essentially offered net book and<br />

rested. Despite the inevitable loss of the presumption of<br />

net book it provided no facts to support its position, only<br />

Dr. Tierney's "economic model" which the Board disbelieved.


The Board was "not persuaded either by the appellant's<br />

assertions regarding net book value or the evidence<br />

presented to support them." RA. 104.<br />

No valuation witness of any kind was called by<br />

Keyspan. NO one was offered to give any credible assistance<br />

'coward calculating any impact of regulation. RA. 79, 80.<br />

Left only with a discredited, absolute position the Board<br />

therefore found the taxpayer "failed to sustain its burden<br />

of demonstrating that the assessed value of the property at<br />

issue in these appeals was greater than the fair cash<br />

value." RA. 110. That finding is dispositive.<br />

Such failure results in the presumption that the<br />

assessment is valid as a matter of law. J.A. Schlaiker v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Great Barrington, 365 <strong>Mass</strong>. 243, 245<br />

(19741. While Keyspan spends much of its brief challenging<br />

the Board's valuation discussion its complaints are<br />

irrelevant since no substantial evidence i s needed to<br />

support an assessment presumed valid. General Electric Co.<br />

v. Board of Assessors of Lp'm, 393 <strong>Mass</strong>. 591, 600 n.4<br />

(1984). It is "only necessary in this case for the board<br />

to disbelieve the taxpayers' witness to sustain the<br />

ame8sment." Schlaiker, 365 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 246. "Even if the


oard was wholly incorrect" it makea no difference where<br />

the "taxpayers had not met their burden of proof." Id.<br />

Keyspan just pretends this never happened and focuses<br />

on the Board's conclusions rith respect to Watertown and<br />

its findinga on value. Yet so long as there is substantial<br />

evidence for the Board's conclusion concerning the former<br />

the rest is legally irrelevant.<br />

11. Keyspan has extraordinary<br />

evidentiary burdens aince all of its<br />

challengee are to matters entrusted to<br />

the Board.<br />

Among Keyspan'B multiple criticisms of the Board's<br />

decision it i s notable that none allege that it failed to<br />

follow the proper legal standards, particularly the<br />

Watertown line of cases, in every particular. There are<br />

only claims of misconstruing facts, wrongfully interpreting<br />

data or improperly applying valuation techniques.<br />

Keyspan is, therefore, relegated to fighting this<br />

battle on terrain sharply tilted in favor of the Board. To<br />

the extent it has challenged factual findings, these are,<br />

by statute, final. G.L.c. 58A, §13. Challenges to<br />

valuation methodologies are equally fruitless since the<br />

Board's selection and application of those to specific<br />

types of property has always received deference,<br />

12


a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

J<br />

m<br />

e<br />

a<br />

0<br />

e<br />

a<br />

*<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

*<br />

a<br />

.I<br />

a<br />

a<br />

m<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

<strong>Mass</strong>achusetts Institute of Technology v. Board of Assessars<br />

of Cambridge, 422 <strong>Mass</strong>. 447, 452 (1936). (Court must<br />

"respect the board's judgment concerning the feasibility<br />

and fairness of alternate proposed methods cf property<br />

valuation"); General Electric Company, 393 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 605.<br />

Even greater "latitude" is granted the Board when valuing<br />

utility property. Boston Gas Co. v. Assesgors of Boston,<br />

334 <strong>Mass</strong> 549, 580 (1956).<br />

Keyspan's challenges to the Board's conclusions about<br />

the uti]-ity sales, regulation, and the extent to which<br />

either reflect or impact buyers' behavior are also directed<br />

to factual conclusions which, if not final, are entitled to<br />

considerable deference. So long as substantial evidence<br />

exists with respect to any of those matters the court<br />

"defer[sl to the board's judgment on where to draw the<br />

line." Boston Edison v. Boston, 402 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 14.<br />

Keyspan must therefore convince this Court that,<br />

taking the facts a8 final, there is no substantial evidence<br />

for the Board's ultimate conclusions. Tennessee Gas<br />

Pipeline Co. v. Board of Assessors of Agawam, 428 <strong>Mass</strong>.<br />

261, 262 (1998); Sps Corp. v. Commissioner of Revenue, 436<br />

<strong>Mass</strong>. 505, 511 (2002). That standard requires Keyspan to<br />

establish that a "contrary conclusion is not merely<br />

13


a<br />

e<br />

a possible but a necessary inference from the findings.“ Id.<br />

a<br />

6<br />

a<br />

m<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

*<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

*<br />

0<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

8<br />

0<br />

- . .<br />

. ~<br />

quoting Olppia & York State St. Co. v. Board of Assessors<br />

of Boston, 428 <strong>Mass</strong>, 236, 240 (1998).<br />

111. The Board addressed this case<br />

precieely aa Watertown requirea.<br />

Under Watertown and the cases which follow, the<br />

taxpayer’s usual burden of proof is suspended until<br />

assessors present “evidence showing that a potential buyer<br />

would pay more than the net book value” for utility<br />

property. Tennessee Gas Pipeline Co., 428 Mans at 263.<br />

Failing that evidence ”net book value is the proper<br />

valuation method. “ Id. ’<br />

Once there is “some evidence offered by the assessors<br />

to show that, because of such circumstances, the relevance<br />

of [net book value) is put in question”, however, the<br />

2<br />

An unexplained shift has occurred in the standard.<br />

Watertom described the assessor’s burden as demonstrating a<br />

‘possibility”, or “potential” and what “may” or “might”<br />

happen. A “reasonable basis in logic” also sufficed.<br />

Watertown, 387 Ma68. at 304-306. See also Montaup Electric<br />

co. v. Board of Assessors of Wbhitman, 390 <strong>Mass</strong>. 841, 853-<br />

855 (1984). The transformation to proof that a buyer<br />

“would pay more” is plainly inconsistent with the course of<br />

the cases. See e.g. Boston Edison Co. v. Boston, 402 <strong>Mass</strong>.<br />

at 13-14 (addressing the question of whether a price above<br />

net book ‘’might have been paid”; ‘‘a probability, or even a<br />

possibility” is sufficient.)<br />

.<br />

14<br />

. .. . . .. ... .. .. . .


a<br />

e<br />

*<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

burden returns to the taxpayer to show “the absence of such<br />

special circumstances.” Tennessee Gas Pipeline, 428 <strong>Mass</strong>.<br />

at 264, quoting Montaup, 390 Ma8B. at 855. If the taxpayer<br />

fails to meet that burden, it loses the presumption that<br />

net book equals value and the impact of regulation must be<br />

proven and quantified.<br />

concluded that, a8 a factual matter, the regulatory<br />

foundation of Watertown has vanished, raising the question<br />

whether net book had any continuing relevance to valuation,<br />

it analyzed the value of this property precisely as that<br />

case instructs. FA. 85-104.<br />

Although the Board ultimately<br />

IV. The ABseB8OrE met their Watertown burden.<br />

A. The AaaeaaOrB provided substantial<br />

evidence that utility property sells for<br />

greater than ita net book cost.<br />

In the factual section of this brief are three of the<br />

categories of findings which satisfied the ASGeSSOr8‘<br />

burden and showed that “net book value is no longer a<br />

reliable indicator of a regulated utility’s fair market<br />

value.“ RA. 101. This included substantial evidence of<br />

utility sales at greater than the net book cost of the<br />

assets.<br />

I5


a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

*<br />

e<br />

*<br />

m<br />

a<br />

e<br />

0<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

9<br />

This evidence was all undisputed insofar as the data<br />

was concerned so the contest revolved around what it meant.<br />

Keyspan insisted that these were sales of "enterprises" and<br />

were not probative of anything relevant but the AsseSsorR<br />

proved that these premiums were primarily paid to acquire<br />

utility property.<br />

It is important to recognize that utilit,y sales served<br />

two functions in this case. First, the mere existence of<br />

sales at greater than net book served as evidence that the<br />

watertown presumption is not true. RA. 79. Second, the<br />

financial details provided "market derived indicator[s]"<br />

which could be used for valuation analysis. RA. 63-69,<br />

3992.<br />

Keyspan spends several pagea arguing that there is no<br />

"necessary correlation" between the sale price of a going<br />

concern and the fair market value of its assets. Brief at:<br />

32-34. No one disputes this- hence Mr. Sansoucy's sales<br />

analysis adjustment of the enterprise sales prices to boil<br />

out the non-utility assets (see infra at 18, n. 3). But<br />

for purposes of meeting the Watertown burden, the ASSeSSOrS<br />

do not need to ahow that the sale price of the enterprise<br />

"correlated" with the value of its property. Rather,<br />

Ih


Keyspan has to show that nane of the huge premiums paid for<br />

the enterprise was attributable to ita property.<br />

As part of both functions the Board was shown six<br />

sales transactions in detail. It was also shown<br />

various submissions by utilities wherein<br />

representations were made concerning the market price<br />

of numerous other sales. See, e.g. RA 1389-1392, 2976,<br />

3039-3040, 3939. Included was Joint Petition of Boston<br />

Edison Co. DTE 99-19 where the DPU calculated that the<br />

average utility sale takee place at mare than twice net<br />

book. RA. 3098. This was ample evidence that sales<br />

above net book were “ubiquitous”. FA. 77.<br />

The Assessors proved not only that sales<br />

invariably take place at amounts greater than net book<br />

but that the premiums paid were “primarily connected<br />

with the value of the utilities’ tangible assets, and<br />

not simply elements of enterprise value.” RA. 78. The<br />

Board had substantial evidence for this finding<br />

including the testimony of the ASSeSEIOrS’ witnesses,<br />

admissions of the Company and industry in “various<br />

regulatory filings and pre-filed testimony relating to<br />

DPU regulatory proceedings” (Id.) and the treatment of<br />

mergers and asset sales by government agencies.<br />

17


Considering all that, the Board simply disbelieved<br />

Keyspan's alternative explanations for the huge<br />

premiums.<br />

A goad deal of Keyspan's rebuttal to the import of<br />

these sales prices was, and is, that the premiums were<br />

paid for more than just utility property. The Board<br />

concluded, however, that Mr. Sansoucy'a analysis<br />

properly "accounted for assets unrelated to rate-<br />

regulated property", and therefore proved that the<br />

property alone also sold above net book. Moreover, he<br />

had provided a reasonable method to extract non-<br />

property assets so that he could perform a comparable<br />

sales analysis. RA. 78. It is well within the<br />

discretion of the Board to credit the testimony.'<br />

Pollard v. Conservation Comiasion of Norfolk, 13 MaSS.<br />

App. Ct. 340, 349 (2008) ("it is the (Board's)<br />

prerogative to determine the probative value of expert<br />

evidence. '' )<br />

-<br />

From the sale price, Mr. sansoucy was able to deduct the<br />

value of current and other assets such as cash, cash<br />

equivalents, tax credit8, gas inventory, pension assets,<br />

and the like. Rh. 66,897-907, 3970-72, 3982 backup detail<br />

at RR. 381-540. For example, $114 million, roughly onequarter<br />

of the price, was determined to be attributable to<br />

non-utility assets in the sale of Colonial Gas to Eastern.<br />

RA. 66, 904. This still left a premium of $85 million<br />

dollars more than the net book of the assets.<br />

18


The Board found Chat some of the figures applied<br />

in Mr. Sansoucy's analysis "required adjustment" and it<br />

independently recalculated the magnitude of the premium<br />

which had been spent for utility property. RA. 5a. For<br />

purposes of the Watertown analysis, however, this<br />

precision is unnecessary to support the BOaTd'8<br />

conclusion that gas utility property sells for<br />

substantially more than its net book cost.<br />

The Board was also shown that utility companies well<br />

understand that huge parts of the premiums are being paid<br />

for utility property. This is evident from regulatory<br />

filings, testimony and publications. For example,<br />

Keyspan's claim that prices paid in enterprise sales are<br />

categorically unrelated to asset value is undermined by the<br />

fact that in its own public disclosures it indiscriminately<br />

mixed asset and enterprise sales in the evaluation of<br />

market prices. RA. 1389-1392, 1225-1226.'<br />

Keyspan's regulatory filings also provided<br />

"confirmation of the analysis of the assessors' experts."<br />

RA. 78. Mr. Bodanza was called to the stand by Keyspan to<br />

discuss the Colonial Gas sale and insisted that Eastern did<br />

'The material at RA. 1225-1226 was created by Mr. Sansoucy<br />

and reflects the form of the transactions Keyspan used when<br />

making its presentation shown at RA. 1389.<br />

19


not spend this money for utility property but for an<br />

“entire enterprise”, the “whole entity”, including a<br />

subsidiary called Transgas. RA. 3600-01.<br />

The Board then Learned that in pre-filed testimony<br />

to the D.P.U. Mr. Bodanza had explained the transaction<br />

quite differently. There he said that, after deducting<br />

$8 million dollars of the premium paid for Transgas, “an<br />

up-front acquisition premium of $199.2 million will be<br />

paid to accomplish the acquisition of Colonial’a gas<br />

distribution operations. (Emphasis added)”. RA. 614.<br />

Having effectively camed out any Colonial subsidiaries<br />

or non-gas distribution side businesses by that<br />

statement, Mr. Bodanza proceeded to reveal to what the<br />

value of the “operations” (enterprise) was really<br />

attributable- the gas distribution operations‘<br />

“underlying assets” which he further described as<br />

”primarily mains and services.” RA 616.<br />

In a similar fashion Keyspan certified to the<br />

Securities and Exchange Commission pursuant to 15<br />

U.S.C. 5 79j(b)(2) that the price it was paying for<br />

Eastern’s stock was wholly justified by the utility<br />

property it was buying. The enterprise price, it<br />

20


eported, bare “a fair relationship to the investment<br />

in and earning capacity of the utility assets<br />

underlying the securities being acquired.” m. 3232-<br />

3233. This company filing proved not only that Keyopan<br />

acknowledged that the value of the enterprise was<br />

primarily the ”utility assets”, but reflected that the<br />

SEC measures the reasonableness of an “enterprise” sale<br />

by the value of the underlying utility assets, that<br />

Keyspan and the SEC found reasonable a sale price of<br />

more than double net book, and that a real market<br />

exists, one where price is set “a8 a result of a<br />

competitive process and substantial arm’s length<br />

negotiation.“ RA. 3233.<br />

The fact is that, except for certain obvious<br />

adjustrnenta, the “enterprise“ is the property when<br />

dealing with public utilities. This was the gist of<br />

the testimony of David Effron, an accountant who had<br />

participated in more than 250 utility cases. Mr.<br />

Effron showed that acquisition premiums are “primarily<br />

associated with the purchase of regulated assete.” RA.<br />

75. Unlike Mr. Bodanza, who “simply asserted” the<br />

contrary, RA. 25, Mr. Gffron proved his point with two<br />

successive transactions involving the same property.<br />

21<br />

!


The 2000 transaction, see RA. 841, 673. was an<br />

"enterprise" sale in which Southern Union Company<br />

purchased three gas companies and four small<br />

unregulated businesses. National Grid's 2006<br />

acquiaition, by contrast, RA. 3886, 842, 754, was the<br />

purchase of the same gas ccmpany property but<br />

structured as an asset purchase, a form made inevitable<br />

by the fact that the "enterprises" Southern Union had<br />

acquired had since been dissolved. RA. 3886.<br />

The first sale therefore included all of the<br />

enterprise attributes, goodwill and going concern value<br />

to which Keyspan attributes the multi-million dollar<br />

premiums. The second sale had none of that, only pipe,<br />

valves, gas inventory, and other tangible assets. RA.<br />

4171-4172. Despite the different transactional<br />

structures the price was almost exactly the same in<br />

both sales. The enterprise attributes held no value<br />

whatsoever. RA. 841, 842, 3888-3891.<br />

Mr. Effron's example is illustrative of the fact that<br />

there is really no significant difference between the<br />

purchase of a utility company and the acquisition of its<br />

property. The structure of the transaction may be designed<br />

to accomplish a Like/kind exchange, PA. 801, or tax free<br />

22


eorganization, FA. 3145, 2917, but, as the Board found,<br />

"the record before it did not reveal a distinction between<br />

enterprise value and the value of regulated assets that<br />

would accaunt for an appreciable portion of the premium."<br />

RA. 102.<br />

The rules and practices of the several agencies which<br />

regulate utilities demonstrate this as well. The Public<br />

Utility Holding Company Act', for example, called for<br />

Securities and Exchange Commission review of "the<br />

acquisition of securities or utility assets" and resulted<br />

in the Keyspan certification referenced above. The statute<br />

groups both reviews in the same sentence, under the same<br />

atandards and for the same purpose. 15 U.S.C. §79j(b) (2).<br />

<strong>Mass</strong>achusetts similarly combines authorization for<br />

utilities to "consolidate or merge with one another, or<br />

sell or convey their properties to another of such<br />

companies ..." G.L.c. 164, 9 96. The authority and standard,<br />

for mergers, RA. 3070, 3568, and pure asset sales, and the<br />

"case by case review" principle (Id.; RA. 590-591, 35201,<br />

are used interchangeably because they are effectively the<br />

same transaction.<br />

'The Act, 15 U.S.C. 5s 79-792-6 wasrepealedin 2005 but in<br />

effect during the years at issue.<br />

23


Utility accounting rules also require identical<br />

treatment of mergers and asset sales with the acquisition<br />

premium from each accounted for in the same manner. RA.<br />

3881-82. Indeed the entire "carryover rate base" policy<br />

which underpins Keyspan's single approach to value is a<br />

product of merger cases. See, Everett, 20 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Tax<br />

Ed. 77 at 120 n.10; m. 175 n.47, 48.<br />

All of this evidence showed prima facie that the sales<br />

occur at huge premiums over net book and that a large part<br />

of these premiuma are paid for the taxable property of the<br />

utility. The burden was therefore on Keyspan to rebut that<br />

evidence and show that in each case only the net book cast<br />

of the assets was paid to acquire them.<br />

B. eyep pan failed to rebut the Assessore' ealee<br />

evidence at trial and cannot eatablish that the<br />

Board lacked substantial evidence for its<br />

findings.<br />

The Board's factual findings with respect to the<br />

sales evidence are final. G.L.c. 58, § 13. To prevail<br />

Keyspan must therefore convince the Court that the<br />

Board erred because, on the facts found, it is a<br />

"necessary inference" that no part of any premiums paid<br />

in these transactions could be for the purchase of<br />

utility property. Keyspan's evidence remains nothing<br />

24


ut unsupported insistence that under no circumstances<br />

would anyone ever pay more than net book €or regulated<br />

utility property because utility rates '*net' value. RA.<br />

3509, 162 n.24.<br />

i.Keyapan had no affirmative evidence<br />

showing that utility property only<br />

sella for it8 net book coat.<br />

Keeping the Boston Gas acquisition in mind, Keyspan's<br />

burden can be formulated as having to attribute all of its<br />

$750 million dollar premium to anything but Boston Gas's<br />

utility property. At trial Keyspan attempted this in<br />

several ways. First it presented two witnesses. Mr.<br />

Bodanza, as the Board observed, "simply asserted" that the<br />

premium was for "some unspecified element of Eastern's<br />

enterprise." RA. 25. The Board justifiably discounted his<br />

testimony.<br />

Dr. Tierney was the main witneas for Keyspan on this<br />

point. She stuck by her guns and remained admirably<br />

consistent, if not credible, while insisting that BOStOn<br />

Gas's property would never sell for more than net book.<br />

Yet shackled to hex theory she then had to affirm that a<br />

strategically critical and practically irreplaceable 12<br />

million barrel cryogenic gas tank currently has a value of<br />

zero. RA. 3645. Her theory requires that three million<br />

25


a<br />

m<br />

e<br />

a<br />

m<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

e<br />

*<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

m<br />

a<br />

a<br />

*<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

feet of working, income producing, gas pipe, RA. 4115, and<br />

twenty million dollars worth of new, but yet unueed,<br />

utility property is also worth nothing. RA. 3646.<br />

Similarly, her net book catechism required that she claim<br />

that 30 plus acres of waterfront land in Boston is worth<br />

about the same, ($368,196) RA. 287, as a three bedroom<br />

house in norcheater, and demands one believe that property<br />

which would annually generate $35 million in profit would<br />

be worth only $24 million on the market. RA. 3948-3949.<br />

When asked to step out6ide of her "economic model,"<br />

RA. 3553, Dr. Tierney offered nothing backing her claim<br />

save an insignificant DPU order ratifying two companies'<br />

decade old agreement that one be allowed to park a piece of<br />

property with the other and buy it back later at its net<br />

book cost.' RA. 166, n.37. Essentially Dr. Tierney defended<br />

her ground with circular logic and admitted she had no<br />

actual evidence. When asked whether she could testify<br />

that, in fact, in transactions with which she was familiar<br />

all sums paid above net book cast were for something other<br />

' Keyspan repeatedly harps on this case, FW. 585-596,<br />

lamenting that the Board "simply omitted'' any consideration<br />

of it. Brief at 29. Its circumstances, particularly that<br />

it never "ordered" anything, just "approved" the sale<br />

agreement of the parties, is sufficient to justify why it<br />

was ignored. RA. 593.<br />

26


than utility property she could only admit *I don't know<br />

that." RA. 3553.<br />

The Board found no backing for the testimony of Mr.<br />

Bodanza or, on this point, that of Dr. Tietney either. The<br />

Board's conclusion that testimony is deficient is a finding<br />

of fact and final. Schlaiker, 365 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 245.<br />

ii. Keyepan had no evidence that the aales<br />

premiums were paid far other than<br />

utility property.<br />

In addition to her affirmative economic model, Keyspan<br />

also used Dr. Tierney to try and rebut the Asse8sors'<br />

market sales information, the overwhelming evidence which<br />

"particularly" impressed the Board by showing that buyers<br />

regularly pay more than net book for regulated utility<br />

property. RA. 102-103. Her principal approach, relied upon<br />

again in Keyspan's brief, was to deny that any conclusions<br />

can be reached becauee these sales usually include more<br />

than just utility property. FA. 3543, 3553.<br />

Keyspan's first cut was to claim that since most<br />

sellers were holding companies the premiums were actually<br />

paid for affiliates and unregulated income streams of the<br />

acquired entity. RA. 156, 3486-3489. The surface appeal of<br />

this challenge was undermined by the breakdown of the<br />

Eastern sale for which Keyspan's om records eliminated all<br />

21


e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

e<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

*<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

8<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

0<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

a<br />

of the affiliates and isolated the sale price of Boston<br />

Gas. RA. 668. Meanwhile Boaton Gas's DPU filing showed<br />

that in the relevant year it had no other source of revenue<br />

f<br />

but that generated by its utility property. The BOaTd'B<br />

review of all of the other sales similarly caused it to<br />

reject the claim that "unrelated businesses, regulated or<br />

otherwise, accounted for all or even an appreciable portion<br />

of the acquisition premium." RA. 79.<br />

With the "affiliates and unrelated income" line of<br />

defense undermined, Keyspan next decided to claim the<br />

premiums paid for utility companies are explained by the<br />

need to own the whole company rather than just the<br />

property. Arguing that the three quarters of a billion<br />

dollars was paid so that Keyspan could assume the helm of<br />

"The Enterprise" like some publicly traded Captain Kirk,<br />

Dr. Tierney beamed down a list of intangible enterprise<br />

attributes which she claimed justified the $750 million.<br />

None had the benefit of either factual support or common<br />

sense. RA. 79-80, 102, 174, 3490.<br />

"Intellectual property" was the first. That is an<br />

item which appears never to have been an asset of Boston<br />

' Boston Gas had revenue of $650,000,000 in 2000 of which<br />

only $515,507 (.000786%) was not produced by the utility<br />

property as 'sales" ox "Trans. gas of others." RA.1968.<br />

28


a<br />

a<br />

*<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

m<br />

0<br />

a<br />

*<br />

0<br />

a<br />

e<br />

0<br />

a<br />

*<br />

a<br />

e<br />

Gas and no example was offered of what this might mean for<br />

a company that pushes gas through a pipe. PA. 3692.<br />

Intellectual property is not a category in the Boston Gas<br />

nor DPU standardized Uniform syatem of Accounts. FA. 1941,<br />

1946-1949, 971-1136, 4007.<br />

"Brand name" was the next intangible asset proffered<br />

by Dr. Tierney. RA. 3691. Certainly her credibility was<br />

not aided by her insistence that this contributed to the<br />

sale price of an entity whose iconic gas tank and fleet of<br />

vehicles had the brand name sanded off and replaced with a<br />

new name twice in the eight years &fore the trial. RA. 79-<br />

80 ~<br />

The next supposed explanation was "customer base".<br />

This asset has real value to certain types of business but<br />

is difficult to justify when every customer is captive to<br />

monopoly service. FA 4006. Mr. Charles Phillips, an author<br />

on these matters relied upon by Dr. Tierney, RA. 162,n.24,<br />

recognized that with public utilities "no specific value<br />

can be attached to the company-customer relationship."<br />

Phillips, The Regulation of Public Utilities at 351 (3'd,<br />

Ed. 1993) ("Phillips"); RA. 3689. The Same point was made<br />

by this Court in Stow which explained that there i s no<br />

29


a<br />

enhancement in value to an enterprise from a "largely<br />

captive class of customers." Stow 426 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 346.<br />

Management "acumen" and workforce "attributes" were<br />

also pushed forward as an explanation for the premium. Yet<br />

no one, at leaat no one without a contract, is an asset of<br />

the company subject to sale. Moreover, the reality belies<br />

the claim since in each successive acquisition the<br />

management of the acquired enterprise is largely<br />

jettisoned. RA. 4172, 4006, 3620-21.<br />

As for the workforce it is also not an asset available<br />

to be sold. Further, the sales value DE the workforce is<br />

questionable in an industry where much of the work is<br />

subcontracted, PA. 3854, and in which the existing<br />

employees are more of an albatross than a benefit; a point<br />

starkly demonstrated by the promises to regulators and<br />

unions to preserve jobs. RA. 3071, 767, 2952. 3036, 4169.<br />

Indeed, the hypocriay of the claim that Keyspan spent<br />

$750 million for Boston Gas's "workforce" is borne out by<br />

the fact that a bare few pages after ite brief touts these<br />

supposed "significant value elements", workforce becomes<br />

the chaff which is sa bloodlessly and efficiently milled<br />

away after a merger to create "synergies." Brief at 32; RA.<br />

30


a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

m<br />

e<br />

0<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

e<br />

a<br />

0<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

e<br />

a<br />

m<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

0<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

*<br />

4007. After all, what eLae axe "post-merger cost savings<br />

from reduction of duplicative staff, facilities and systems<br />

plua resultant economies of scale,'' Brief at 35, but proof<br />

positive that the motivation of the buyer is that it only<br />

really wants the property?<br />

As the last fire break against the increasingly<br />

obvious Keyspan offers up that the premiums are paid for<br />

business values which can only be identified aa the<br />

mysterious ether that is left over when everything else is<br />

accounted for; goodwill and "going concern" value. Brief at:<br />

33-35.<br />

These are values which clearly exist in some<br />

businesses; the New England Patriots, a case cited by<br />

Keyspan, being a good example. Utilities, however, have<br />

state owned and controlled franchises and captive<br />

customers. G.L. c. 164, § 21; AttOfney General v. Haverhill<br />

Gas Light Co., 215 <strong>Mass</strong>. 394 (1913). They are not among<br />

businesses with any "going concern" value. This court has<br />

said preViOU6ly that goodwill and going concern value are.<br />

"considerationa that do not apply to a regulated monopoly".<br />

Stow, 426 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 346. Going concern "is a social value<br />

and belongs to the public instead of the public utility<br />

company." Phillips, at 353: RA, 3693.<br />

31


Keyspan's argument requires one to accept that, in the<br />

case of its own purchase, it attributed more than triple<br />

the value to Boston Gas's intangible "enterprise"<br />

attributes than it did to the property that generates<br />

93.9993% of the revenue. The Board had ample basis €or<br />

rejecting Keyspan's unsupported and counterintuitive claims<br />

that the sales premiums were wholly explained by these<br />

vague theoretical enterprise attributes.<br />

iil. Neither the seller'@ exieting rates<br />

nor expenses determine what will be<br />

paid to buy the property.<br />

Keyspan makes additional arguments that the sales<br />

prices should be disregarded because they reflect only<br />

value unique to the entire enterprise, and not the value of<br />

utility property, The first reason offered is that<br />

acquisition of the enterprise is supposedly necessary<br />

because the buyer needs to employ the seller's "rate order<br />

in place" in order to obtain net revenues sufficient to<br />

justify the premium. Brief at 28. In a similar vein it<br />

claims that the "substantially reduced" expenses which the<br />

buyer of the utility property might enjoy will not be<br />

available unless the entire company is bought. Brief at 35-<br />

37. These latest attempts to find some value in the<br />

"enterprise" simply confirm that Keyspan has no evidence<br />

32


whatsoever disproving what is apparent-a buyer gets nothing<br />

of any substantial value by buying the company compared to<br />

just buying the property.<br />

With respect to the first point it is true that<br />

because a merger is a more common form of acquisition,<br />

"freezing" che existing rate structure typically provides<br />

the baseline against: which operational savings are measured<br />

and the recovery of an acquisition premium justified.<br />

However nothing but the parties' election to structure the<br />

transaction as a merger results in recovery of the premium<br />

in that fashion. A different approach was taken in Joint<br />

Petition of Boston Edison Co., DTE 99-19 where the DPU<br />

encouraged the merger by expressly promising that recovery<br />

of the acquisition premium would be a necessary part of<br />

"any future rate proceeding',. RA. 3067-3068, 3112. The<br />

DPU's approach in these transactions is ''tailored to<br />

circumstances presented," RA. 3111, and if the buyer of<br />

just Boston GaS'Q utility property could demonstrate that,<br />

after incorporating the property into its system, there<br />

would be a net gain to ratepayers the DPU would surely set<br />

rates to facilitate the transaction.<br />

Keyspan's second argument is that no one would buy<br />

just the property, as opposed to the company, because there<br />

33


is "no possible cost reduction" if one just buys the<br />

property and the "acquired company's operating costs-would,<br />

of course, not be subject to post-acquisition reduction in<br />

a sale of tangible personal property alone." Brief at 32,<br />

35-31.<br />

To the contrary, the acquired company's operating<br />

costs would be more than reduced; they would be eliminated<br />

upon the sale of the personal property alone. In their<br />

place would be the acquiring company's operating costs<br />

which, Keyspan has already acknowledged, would be<br />

"substantially reduced" because of economies of scale and<br />

synergies. Brief at 36. Keyspan cannot, and never attempts<br />

to, explain why it claims the synergies are unavailable<br />

unless the property is acquired enmeshed with all those<br />

redundant expenses with which the enterprise is saddled.<br />

Keyspan also seema to make a legal argument that the<br />

ability of a buyer to operate the property more profitably<br />

should not be treated a8 an attribute of the property but<br />

as one of the selling enterprise and this supposedly<br />

invalidates the relevance of the sale price. Yet<br />

consideration of that fact is required to properly value<br />

the property.<br />

34


‘To provide sound value indications, the appraiser<br />

must carefully address and forecast investors’<br />

expectations or changes in income levels, the<br />

expenses required to ensure income, and probable<br />

increases or decreases in property value.”<br />

Appraisal Institute, The Appraisal of Real Estate at 446<br />

(13th Ed. 2008).<br />

The goal i s the net income “attributable to” the<br />

property. Analogic Cow. v. Board of Assessors of Peabody,<br />

45 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Ct. 605, 612 (1998). See also Boston Gas, 334<br />

<strong>Mass</strong>. at 570; Assessors of Quincy 309 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 67 (the<br />

“earning capacity of this underground system for the<br />

distribution and sale of gas”) (emphasis added).<br />

Forecasting changes from the experience of the current<br />

owner is not only allowed, it is necessary for a valid<br />

appraisal. Appraisal of Real Estate at 481.’<br />

For BoBton Gas all of the income is generated by use<br />

of the rate regulated utility property. Buyers of the<br />

property believed they could operate more efficiently. RA.<br />

That savings may be generated by firing telephone<br />

operators OK billing clerks, not those operating the pipes.<br />

does not matter. See, e.g. Peterson v. Board of Assessors<br />

of Boston, 62 Masa. App. Ct. 428. 435 (2004) (calculating<br />

net income by deducting “general and administrative costs,<br />

property management fees, security costs, repair and<br />

maintenance, cleaning, utilities, insurance and<br />

miscellaneous nonreimbursable expenses”), Appraisal of Real<br />

Estate at 486 (deducting accounting, legal, clerical help,<br />

postage and advertiaing).<br />

35


3262-3264. This contributes to what they were willing to<br />

pay for the property just like anticipation of savings in<br />

energy costs, security, snow removal, or management fees<br />

would affect the price paid for an office building or strip<br />

mall.<br />

C. Substantial changes in regulatory<br />

policy permit sales at more than<br />

net book coat.<br />

The Board went into considerable detail tracing the<br />

“marked” changes in DPU policy which, during the tax years,<br />

was in “sharp contrast“ to that at the time of Watertown.<br />

RA. 97, 99. It found that a case-by-case treatment of a<br />

request to recover an acquisition premium plus “DPU’s<br />

adoption of performance-based rates ._. constituted a change<br />

in regulatory policy that in many instances will affect the<br />

price paid ...”. FS. 99.<br />

Keyspan disputes these conclusions arguing that the<br />

1993 Mergers and Acquisitions decision was the high water<br />

mark of any expectations that a buyer of the property might<br />

recover and profit on an amount paid greater than net book.<br />

Never mind that Stow found otherwise four years later,<br />

Keyspan insists that after 1993 it was “less, not more,<br />

likely” that a buyer would anticipate such recovery. Brief<br />

at 27.<br />

34


The first response to this argument is to take it from<br />

the other direction and point: out that even if Xeyspan is<br />

correct and the policy i s stricter than ever, DPU policy<br />

has demonstrably not restricted sale of utility property to<br />

net book. The Watertown theory was a hypothetical economic<br />

exercise and, lacking sales data, the court did not pretend<br />

otherwise. But even if regulation is unchanged, the market<br />

proves the impact of the policy is not as predicted. That<br />

alone is enough to meet the Assessors' burden.’<br />

In any event the change is indisputable. In fact<br />

Keyspan casually concedes that two-thirds of the carry-over<br />

rate base policy has been abolished.<br />

First, as the Board found, the policy “changed from a<br />

mandatory rule always limiting a buyer of utility property<br />

to the seller’s rate base to a case-by-case determination.“<br />

’ This is not particularly surprising. The Watertown<br />

analysis purports to abide by the fair cash value standard<br />

but never considers the seller at all. For Watertom to<br />

work, the seller must be, as expressed by Dr. Tierney,<br />

“indifferent” to the sale price, RA. 3572, something the<br />

market clearly disproves. See, e.g, RA. 3188, (six bidders<br />

for Colonial Gas), RA. 3232-33, (price set after<br />

’competitive process and substantial arm’s length<br />

negotiations”). An equally valid question, never raised in<br />

Watertom, is why would shareholders approve the sale of<br />

utility property at its net book cost, particularly when,<br />

as demonstrated by Mr. Sanaoucy, the cash return to<br />

investors is considerably more than return on rate base.<br />

FA. 666, 3934, 4001-4002.<br />

37


RA. 98-99: Stow 426 Mans. at 347. See also Attorney General<br />

v. Department of Telecommunications and Energy, 430 <strong>Mass</strong>.<br />

256, 263 (2002); Petition of Boston Ga8 Co. DTE 03-40 RA.<br />

2716 11.337. Keyspan blithely accepts that "of course" the<br />

matter ia "unvaryingly" handled on a case-by-case basis,<br />

Brief at 27, unaware of, or ignoring, the fact that this<br />

Court has already held that single policy change alone was<br />

"certainly" enough to support the same weighing of RCNLE<br />

and net book used in thia case. Stow, 426 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 347.<br />

A second change is similarly conceded then avoided by<br />

Keyspan. Watertown clearly assumed, and indeed the carry-<br />

over rate base policy formerly provided, that a buyer of<br />

property at greater than net book could nat receive a<br />

return on the acquisition premium and would not receive a<br />

return of it either. RA. 166. Keyspan references that the<br />

new DPU policy is one of case-by-case consideration<br />

'permitting recovery of an acquisition premium" but then it<br />

changes the subject to assert that "no case" has allowed a<br />

"step-up in rate base". Brief at 26, 28.<br />

Not so fast. This Court has specifically acknowledged<br />

that the DPU has "reversed its previous policy of per se<br />

disallowance of recovering an acquisition premium."<br />

Attorney General, 438 <strong>Mass</strong> at 263. And Keyspan concedes<br />

38


that under the new policy the UPU has allowed "the<br />

opportunity for the recovery of a premium". Brief at 28;<br />

RA. 3511. Most cases shown the Board permitted the buyer<br />

tc recover the acquisition premim one way or another. FA.<br />

2980. 3112, 3162.<br />

Therefore two of the three elements of the old carry-<br />

over rate base policy are admittedly gone.<br />

There is now a<br />

case-by-case determination and the buyer inevitably also<br />

gets the return of the entire purchase price. Either<br />

change- let alone both- is sufficient to justify the<br />

Board's conclusion.<br />

AB to the third element, a return on the premium, the<br />

buyer obviously expects to recover it. Returning to the<br />

Keyspan purchase of Boston Gas the aCquiSitiOn premium was<br />

"puahed down" to the books of the Boston Gas. FA. 1867 n.*.<br />

See Attorney General, 438 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 263. This required that<br />

the property generate an additional $22,665,437 annually to<br />

repay it. See also RA. 3318. Keyspan also "pushed down"<br />

$650 million of the debt onto the books of Boston Gas. RA.<br />

2708-2710, n.136. This was booked by Boston Gas as an<br />

"advance from Keyspan" and repaid to it with interest at<br />

7.78a-another $49,834,072 per year. RA. 1884,3991, 4117-18.<br />

39


True no premium went into rate base, but that money all<br />

found its way to the buyer.<br />

The Board also found that another regulatory change,<br />

PBR, undercut the premise of the Watertom case.<br />

RA. 99. PER rate plans "replace the traditional cost-of<br />

service/rate of return method for setting company<br />

distribution rates." PetiCion of BOStOn Gas, DTE 03-40 at<br />

RA. 2829.<br />

PBR are rates intended to create an incentive for<br />

operational efficiency. The reward, as DK. Tierney<br />

explained, is PBR "would allow for an increase in return,"<br />

to the company, RA. 3589, or, as this Court has described<br />

it, they wkeepIlthe extra" profits. Boston Gas C0.v.<br />

Department of Telecommunications and Energy, 436 Ma88. 233,<br />

235 (2002). This falls within Watertown's third category<br />

by which an Assessor can show that the property might sell<br />

€or more that net book cost - the 'return actually being<br />

earned by the utility exceed" the approved rate of<br />

return. Watertom, 387 <strong>Mass</strong>. at 306 (emphasis added); RA.<br />

3934.<br />

Keyspan attempts to finesse this fact in a curious<br />

fashion, conceding that "an efficient utility may over-earn<br />

under PBR" then trying to avoid the significance of that<br />

40


admiasion with nothing other than an anemic ‘but then again<br />

it may not‘. Brief at 30. Yet that it “may“ is all<br />

Watertom requires to switch the burden back to Keyspan.<br />

With both the policy changes, and the impact on value,<br />

unambiguously expressed by the DPU, the Board easily found<br />

the “realization” of the regulatory change raised as a<br />

“possibility” in Watertown. RA. 97. Keyspan’s election to<br />

decline any factual inquiry into the degree to which these<br />

new policies affect value, opting instead for total<br />

obeisance to the immutable purity of net book, made the<br />

Board’s treatment of the matter inevitable.<br />

V. With Watertown rebutted Keyepaa had the<br />

burden of overcoming the presumptive<br />

validity of the assesements.<br />

The Board found that the A6SeSSOXS met their burden<br />

under watertown and had offered substantial evidence that<br />

called the relevance of net book coat into question. RA.<br />

80, 83. This left Keyspan with two burdens.<br />

It continued to have the burden discussed above to<br />

show that the valuation placed on its property i s<br />

excessive. Schlaiker, 365 Mam. at 245; Foxboro Associates<br />

v. Board of Assessors of Foxboxauyh, 385 <strong>Mass</strong>. 679, 691<br />

(1982). The Watertown presumption may have sufficed to<br />

meet that burden but it waa rebutted. As a result, because<br />

41


Keyspan continued to rely exclusively on the alleged effect<br />

of regulation, it nww had to "prove the effect" of that<br />

regulation. Reliable Electronic Finishing Co., fnc. v.<br />

Board of Assessors of Canton, 410 Maso. 381, 382<br />

(effect of contamination); h'ampton Associates v.<br />

Assessors of Northampton, 52 <strong>Mass</strong>. App. Ct. 110<br />

(effect of rent restrictims); Montaup, 390 <strong>Mass</strong><br />

(1991)<br />

Board of<br />

2001)<br />

at 854.<br />

It failed to meet either burden when it declined to offer<br />

anything but theories.<br />

Although it never offered any valuation evidence at<br />

all Ksyspan now raises several other methods by which it<br />

says it undercut the assessment. First it argues that<br />

supposed "inconsistencies" between Mr. Sansoucy's trial<br />

appraisal and assessment appraisal are enough to meet its<br />

burden. Brief at 44. The changes alluded to were in fact<br />

largely refinements, frequently rendered posaible by more<br />

complete information collected in discovery. RA. 3932,<br />

3933. All were explained to the Board which was,<br />

justifiably, more impressed by Mr. Sancoucy's work than it<br />

was concerned that methodological changes or recalculatione<br />

were made in the intervening 4 years. RA. 4013-4020.<br />

Keyapan's other complaint is that the Board ignored<br />

evidence of the assessment of other utility property; a<br />

42


minor system owned by someone else in Hyde Park as well as<br />

assessments of Boston Gas property in BO other communities.<br />

Brief at 42-44. This was evidence the Board correctly<br />

determined was of “no probative value”. Rh. 35.<br />

In the first circumstance the property at issue was<br />

about 3.6% of the value of Boston Gas’s system. It hardly<br />

merited a full blown appraisal for submission to the<br />

Department of Revenue. RA. 3370, 3360. With respect to<br />

the values set by the 80 other communities, their falling<br />

into line to assess the property at net book reflects both<br />

the ciirrent prerequisites for deviating from net book and,<br />

perhaps, the towns’ reluctance to do so in the face of the<br />

utilities’ demonstrated propensity for flexing their<br />

muscles against the likes of Agawam, Whitman and Watertown.<br />

In any event, neither comparison say8 anything about the<br />

value of the property at issue here.<br />

VI. Keyapan’e other criticisms are irrelevant,<br />

immaterial and largely incorrect.<br />

In the face of a record which proved without serious<br />

question that utility property sells at huge premiums over<br />

net book, that the carry-over rate baae has been modified<br />

to the point that the Watertown presumptions no longer<br />

43


apply, and that pure cost of service rate making has been<br />

replaced, Keyspan rested on unsubstantiated theory.<br />

Keyspan's brief ignores its complete failure to provide<br />

evidence that the as~essrnant was in error and takes off on<br />

a line of criticisms of the Board's enlightening, but<br />

legally superfluous, valuation decision. Even if Keyspan's<br />

complicated recalculations and hyper technical critiques<br />

matter they fail to justify remand for three major reasons.<br />

First, every one of Keyspan's demanded adjustments,<br />

singly or together, results in a valuation which still<br />

dwarfs the assessment of $223,200,000. RA. 108-103. That<br />

is because, deapite the conservative approach the Board<br />

took, it is apparent it was convinced by Mr. Sansoucy's<br />

analysis. After making the adjustments it felt were<br />

required, the Board determined that the value of the<br />

personal Property was $336,848,000. RA. 108.<br />

After deriving that figure the Board then proceeded to<br />

"account (for) the contemporaneous regulatory environment"<br />

and averaged the number with net book. Id. Yet if there is<br />

a lack of substantial evidence for anything the Board did<br />

in this case it was its decision to water down its real<br />

conclusions by performing this calculation. As the Board<br />

recognized. economic depreciation, derived from actual<br />

44


income and sales data and part of Mr. Sansoucy's analysis,<br />

already accounted for any effect of regulation. RA. 48-49,<br />

3932. There is no justification in the record or in theory<br />

for accounting for "the regulatory environment" again by<br />

averaging the derived value with net book.<br />

The Board acknowledged it had a "significant question"<br />

whether net book had any continuing relevance. RA. 100. It<br />

appears obvioua that two practical considerations led to<br />

its decision to average. First, it wished to remain<br />

"consistent with [I precedent", RA. 107, and to use "the<br />

combined valuation approachea ratified by" this Court in<br />

Boston and Stow. PA. 109. Second, it seems likely the<br />

Board accepted the averaging technique for the same reason<br />

the AsseSSOrS did not cross appeal on this point. Even<br />

with the averaging the result still exceeded the assessment<br />

by more than $20 million.<br />

Second, Keyspan's criticisms all address matters left<br />

by law to the judgment of the Board. The decision<br />

demonstrates this was hardly a sloppy or ill considered<br />

outcome, where the Board Eound an error or felt there<br />

should be an adjustment which had a material effect, it<br />

adopted what it considexed to be the proper figures and<br />

performed its own calculations. IC changed Mr. Sansoucy's<br />

45


operation and maintenance costs, RA. 53-4, his economic<br />

depreciation percentage, RA. 55, his sale price to net book<br />

ratio, RA. 68, and ultimately his opinion of value. Beyond<br />

that the Baard found the analysis 'fundamentally sound".<br />

RA. 51.'0<br />

The methodological complaints raised in the brief were<br />

explored below and the Board, for good reason. disagreed<br />

with or found immaterial these alleged "errors." This kind<br />

of microscopic evaluation of the details of the parties'<br />

various expert analyses is justifiably left to the judgment<br />

of the Board which, in this case, heard 21 days of<br />

testimony, fully understood what it wa8 doing, and quite<br />

carefully reached its conclusions. General Electric Co.,<br />

393 Ma88. at 608 ("we defer to the Board's judgment aa to<br />

what evidence to accept and which method or methods of<br />

valuation to rely on."); School Committee of Boeton v.<br />

Io Keyspan relentlessly refers to MT. SanBOuCy's value as<br />

being the exclusive psoduct of an income analysis,<br />

apparently to then tee up allegations of methodological<br />

flaws. Brief at 13, 22, 50. A8 the Board understood, Mr.<br />

Sansoucy used 3 approaches to value and primarily<br />

reconciled his cost approach value based on the economic<br />

depreciation revealed by an income approach to account for<br />

rate regulation. RA. 911, 4004-5. His "novel" EBITDA<br />

multiplier is precisely the method Keyspan used to<br />

calculate value in the market. Brief at 4, 13; RA. 1383,<br />

3986.<br />

46


Board of Education, 363 Mags. 125, 128 (1973) (Court's role<br />

not to engage in "complex fact determinations").<br />

Finally, to the extent this Court cares to inspect the<br />

detail of the Board's valuation conclusion, the criticisms<br />

are primarily inaccurate as well as irrelevant and ill<br />

conceived. The alleged failure to "factor for property<br />

taxes" is demonstrably incorrect as ad valorem taxes were<br />

deducted from earnings in the income analysis. RA. 908,<br />

3996, 4099. The logic of the selection of the "anomalies"<br />

which led to Mr. Sansoucy's selecting information from some<br />

years and not others was explained in detail, RA. 3995,<br />

4098, 1430-31, and resulted because Boston Gas had under<br />

reported ita income. The complaint that Mr. Sansoucy used<br />

reproduction cost when replacement cost was appropriate,<br />

Brief at 13 n.8, overlooks his deduction for<br />

"superadequacy" which transforms the reproduction figure to<br />

one representing replacement cost. RA. 3331. The cast iron<br />

main replacement program which would allegedly dampen the<br />

interest of any buyer of the property arose from 1991<br />

regulations and a 1998 DPU order; neither of which appear<br />

to have chilled the ardor of Keyspin to pay a billion<br />

dollars €or the property in 2000. RA. 2426, 3846.<br />

41


a<br />

e<br />

9<br />

e<br />

*<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

e<br />

9<br />

*<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

e<br />

a<br />

a<br />

a<br />

9<br />

e<br />

VIK. BOcLLusB Keyspan also failed to meet ita<br />

burden on the real property the Board<br />

properly affirmed that aeaessment.<br />

Keyspan continues its perplexing approach to the<br />

Commercial Point property by announcing in its Brief that<br />

the property "as a whole suffers from 100% economic<br />

obsoleEce". i.e. it is worth zero. Brief at 47-48. This is<br />

now the fourth different value Keyspan has offered,<br />

following Mr. Logue'a $7.5 million "hypothetical" value for<br />

the land, (a/k/a the one known "to be false", RA.30, 3748),<br />

and his "actual valuation" of the land which is "in<br />

accordance with the expert report of Susan F. 'rierney", PA.<br />

241, which in turn is claimed by Keyspan to be $5E0,595,<br />

Brief at 10, asserted by Mr. Logue to be $388,196, RA. 30,<br />

287, and never quantified at all by Dr. Tierney.<br />

In addition to his wandering figures, Mr. Logue<br />

offered nothing which would meet the requirement that<br />

structures on land be taxed with the land. Dehydrating<br />

Process Co. v. City of Gloucester, 334 <strong>Mass</strong>. 287, 292-293<br />

(1956). Even if his hypothetical contributing land value<br />

(or any of Keyspan's three other numbers) was accepted by<br />

the Board it would then have to somehow be combined with<br />

the value of the tank on the land as to which Mr. L ope was<br />

silent and Keyspan dished up net book.<br />

48


Mr. Lope had other problems. He ignored the highest<br />

and best use of the property to which he himself had<br />

testified. RA. 30-31. He assumed "crucial facts ... that were<br />

at best speculative" and concluded by offering a value<br />

based on circumstances that "under no foreseeable<br />

circumstances could.be realized. " RA. 31.<br />

The quoted findings of the Board are final. The Board<br />

had every reason to discount his testimony and conclude<br />

that, on the land value as well, Keyspan "failed to provide<br />

sufficient probative evidence to establish the fair cash<br />

value of the Commercial Point parcel or to undermine the<br />

value placed upon the property by the ASSeSSOrS." RA. 32.<br />

In this posture the Board has no obligation to accept<br />

Keyspan's invitation to relieve it of its burden, grab one<br />

of the "numbers of land values before the Board €or its<br />

consideration" and determine fair cash value. Brief at 49.<br />

CQNCLUBION<br />

In Mantaup the Board's decision in which it refused to<br />

consider net book cost was remanded by this Court because<br />

there was "no indication" that the assesmr had "presented<br />

any evidence at all", and the Board had "nowhere<br />

explain[ed]" any reasoning yustifying why, anyone would pay<br />

more than the net book cost of that property. In this case<br />

49


the Board extensively evaluated the ieaue exactly as<br />

prescribed, had enormous amounts of compelling evidence and<br />

has supported its findings and reasoning in detail. The<br />

decision of the Board should be affirmed in all. reapects.<br />

Dated: June 18, 2010<br />

Respectfully submitted,<br />

BOARD OF ASSESSORS OF<br />

THE CITY OF BOSTON<br />

By its Attorneys,<br />

navia L. Klebanoff (Bdq #274550)<br />

Gilrnan, McLaughlin & Hanrahan, LLP<br />

101 Merrirnac Street<br />

P. 0. Box 9601<br />

Boston, MA 02114-9601<br />

(617) 227-9999<br />

50

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!