25.06.2013 Views

Impulses for Growth and Employment through Profitable Savings in ...

Impulses for Growth and Employment through Profitable Savings in ...

Impulses for Growth and Employment through Profitable Savings in ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Impulses</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>Growth</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>Employment</strong> <strong>through</strong><br />

<strong>Profitable</strong> <strong>Sav<strong>in</strong>gs</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> Material Resources<br />

Aachen Foundation<br />

Schmiedstraße 3<br />

D-52062 Aachen<br />

Tel +49 241 409 29 0<br />

<strong>in</strong>fo@aachener-stiftung.de<br />

Commissioned by<br />

Authors<br />

Dr. Jan<strong>in</strong>a Scheelhaase Dr. Karl Lichtblau<br />

Senior Manager Macro Economics Director<br />

Prognos AG Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft Köln<br />

Consult GmbH<br />

Prof. Dr. Bernd Meyer Dr. Hartmut Fischer<br />

Director Senior Manager<br />

Gesellschaft für wirtschaftliche Arthur D. Little GmbH<br />

Struktur<strong>for</strong>schung GmbH<br />

Translation Michael Schatzschneider


Hartmut Fischer, Karl Lichtblau, Bernd Meyer, Jan<strong>in</strong>a Scheelhaase<br />

<strong>Impulses</strong> <strong>for</strong> <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Employment</strong> <strong>through</strong><br />

<strong>Profitable</strong> <strong>Sav<strong>in</strong>gs</strong> <strong>in</strong> Material Resources<br />

Industry is cont<strong>in</strong>ually mak<strong>in</strong>g an ef<strong>for</strong>t to reduce both material costs of products <strong>and</strong><br />

material <strong>in</strong>put of production. What k<strong>in</strong>d of effects on the national economy can be<br />

expected from material sav<strong>in</strong>gs that are profitable on a s<strong>in</strong>gle-company basis? What<br />

are the conditions under which new jobs develop?<br />

Material sav<strong>in</strong>gs on a s<strong>in</strong>gle-company basis<br />

(dematerialization) beyond the presentday<br />

trend has strong positive effects on<br />

the national economy. It strengthens Germany’s<br />

competitive position, provides<br />

growth, contributes to the consolidation of<br />

public budgets <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>creases real <strong>in</strong>come<br />

of private households. As is the case <strong>in</strong><br />

any k<strong>in</strong>d of productivity <strong>in</strong>crease, labour<br />

market effects of a profitable dematerialization<br />

are also dependent upon concomitant<br />

wage developments.<br />

Unused S<strong>in</strong>gle-Company Potentials<br />

Because of the high importance of material<br />

<strong>through</strong>put costs <strong>in</strong>dustry cont<strong>in</strong>uously<br />

reduces material <strong>through</strong>put by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

material efficiency of production <strong>and</strong> products.<br />

Per Euro of gross national product,<br />

material <strong>in</strong>put fell by an <strong>in</strong>flation-adjusted<br />

42% between 1960 <strong>and</strong> 1990 1 . This trend<br />

toward “profitable dematerialization” of<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustrial value added rema<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>tact <strong>and</strong><br />

is also evidenced by the 2002 Innovation<br />

Prize of the German Economy: the awardw<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g<br />

products were conv<strong>in</strong>c<strong>in</strong>g essentially<br />

<strong>through</strong> their reduced material<br />

<strong>through</strong>put costs <strong>in</strong> the product life cycle 2 .<br />

This paper evolved from an assignment by the<br />

Aachen Foundation Kathy Beys to the authors <strong>for</strong><br />

the purpose of carry<strong>in</strong>g the issue of dematerialization<br />

<strong>in</strong>to professional circles <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>to the political<br />

arena.<br />

1 H<strong>in</strong>terberger, F., S. Renn, H. Schütz, Arbeit, Wirtschaft,<br />

Umwelt, Wuppertal Paper No. 89, Wuppertal,<br />

1999, p. 12<br />

2 Manager Magaz<strong>in</strong>, Spezial Innovationspreis, 16<br />

January 2003, pp. 64-83. MTU Aero developed an<br />

aeroplane turb<strong>in</strong>e with reduced energy consumption,<br />

Leica Microsystems extended the useful economic<br />

life of expensive optics used <strong>in</strong> chip production<br />

quality assurance, Solvent Innovation devel-<br />

Nevertheless, a dist<strong>in</strong>ctly greater harvest<strong>in</strong>g<br />

of potentials by <strong>in</strong>dustry is possible.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g only two <strong>in</strong>struments, <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>stance,<br />

the consultancy company Arthur D. Little<br />

GmbH regularly reduces the material<br />

<strong>through</strong>put costs of companies by a total<br />

of 20%:<br />

• Us<strong>in</strong>g “Zero Loss Management” material<br />

<strong>and</strong> energy losses <strong>in</strong> the supply<br />

cha<strong>in</strong> are reduced <strong>through</strong> improved<br />

cost transparency, task development<br />

by <strong>in</strong>terdiscipl<strong>in</strong>ary teams <strong>and</strong> structured<br />

creativity techniques. Material<br />

exploitation was improved at three<br />

European ice-cream factories of a<br />

large food company, <strong>for</strong> example, by<br />

adjust<strong>in</strong>g process parameters,<br />

strengthen<strong>in</strong>g pre-emptive ma<strong>in</strong>tenance<br />

<strong>and</strong> selective mach<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

With Zero Loss Management<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g costs are regularly reduced<br />

by 5%.<br />

• Us<strong>in</strong>g “Design to Cost”, functions, costbenefit<br />

profiles <strong>and</strong> design of products<br />

are redrafted <strong>in</strong> collusion between<br />

product development, buy<strong>in</strong>g department,<br />

production, customers <strong>and</strong> suppliers.<br />

Life cycle costs of equipment<br />

were reduced at a company produc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

chemical equipment, <strong>for</strong> example, by a<br />

more <strong>in</strong>telligent <strong>and</strong> material-sav<strong>in</strong>g<br />

construction of equipment components<br />

as well as <strong>in</strong>creased energy efficiency<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g equipment operation. With Design<br />

to Cost, life cycle costs regularly<br />

contribute to a reduction of<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g costs by 15%.<br />

Experience shows that these annual sav<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

are achieved with a one-time <strong>in</strong>vest-<br />

oped ionic fluids that serve to notably <strong>in</strong>crease material<br />

utilisation <strong>in</strong> the chemical <strong>in</strong>dustry.<br />

1


ment with an average payback of twelve<br />

months. About a third of the one-time <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

consists of <strong>in</strong>ternal <strong>and</strong> external<br />

personnel costs <strong>for</strong> task development <strong>and</strong><br />

implementation, the other two-thirds consist<br />

of equipment expenditures.<br />

Other management consultancies have<br />

similar experiences with comparable<br />

methods. Specific eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g methods<br />

<strong>and</strong> technologies herald further potentials 3 .<br />

Barriers<br />

With such a potential the question arises:<br />

Why isn’t it already be<strong>in</strong>g harvested to the<br />

greatest possible extent by <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

companies with<strong>in</strong> a market economy?<br />

General practice shows that “nobody is<br />

perfect”, not even <strong>in</strong>dustry. No company<br />

exists that is <strong>and</strong> stays fully rationalised.<br />

Today, by no means all motivation <strong>and</strong><br />

per<strong>for</strong>mance potentials with respect to<br />

personnel have been tapped. Major optimisation<br />

surges of the past (quality management,<br />

logistics optimisation, outsourc<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess process eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g) could<br />

<strong>for</strong> the most part have been implemented<br />

years earlier. But a critical mass of awareness,<br />

methods <strong>and</strong> qualified multipliers<br />

was necessary <strong>for</strong> the potentials to be<br />

tapped on a large scale.<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g said this it is not quite as astonish<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that potentials <strong>for</strong> profitable dematerialization<br />

have not yet been fully tapped.<br />

Everyday bus<strong>in</strong>ess practice shows a series<br />

of concrete structural barriers st<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong> the way of profitable dematerialization:<br />

• Bus<strong>in</strong>ess decision-makers are often<br />

not aware of the full costs that accrue<br />

with respect to manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> terms<br />

of material losses 4 <strong>and</strong> with respect to<br />

product use <strong>in</strong> terms of material consumption.<br />

This is one reason that<br />

common account<strong>in</strong>g systems either do<br />

not display or <strong>in</strong>completely display<br />

these costs.<br />

3 Cf. <strong>for</strong> example Fachverb<strong>and</strong> Elektrische Antriebe<br />

im Zentralverb<strong>and</strong> Elektrotechnik- und Elektronik<strong>in</strong>dustrie<br />

(ZVEI) e.V. (ed.), Energiesparen mit elektrischen<br />

Antrieben – E<strong>in</strong>sparpotenziale <strong>in</strong> Milliardenhöhe,<br />

Frankfurt 1999.<br />

4 In particular <strong>for</strong> rejects, effluents <strong>and</strong> waste<br />

• Cost reduction is most commonly associated<br />

with the reduction of personnel<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> less commonly with a<br />

reduction of material <strong>through</strong>put costs.<br />

In many cases, this is the reason why<br />

material costs are not reduced as consistently<br />

as personnel costs. In <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

cases this goes as far as cutt<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the budget <strong>for</strong> personnel so str<strong>in</strong>gently<br />

that <strong>in</strong>sufficient capacities rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>for</strong><br />

other cost reduction measures.<br />

• Incentives <strong>for</strong> a company do not automatically<br />

lead to equivalent <strong>in</strong>centives<br />

<strong>for</strong> company decision-makers. Purchas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

departments, <strong>for</strong> <strong>in</strong>stance, are<br />

often controlled <strong>in</strong> accordance with unit<br />

prices rather than the more <strong>in</strong>dicative<br />

life cycle costs of equipment <strong>and</strong> material<br />

purchased. In this way, solutions<br />

prevail on a supra-company basis that<br />

are not always the most economical.<br />

The German Electrical <strong>and</strong> Electronic<br />

Manufacturers’ Association (ZVEI) estimates<br />

that the <strong>in</strong>troduction of appropriate<br />

electric eng<strong>in</strong>es with the most<br />

economical life cycle with<strong>in</strong> German<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry would lead to billions of sav<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

• Company personnel do not consistently<br />

possess the know-how <strong>for</strong> tapp<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the full potential <strong>for</strong> profitable dematerialization.<br />

While the required<br />

methods are not highly complex they<br />

are dem<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> do not yet belong<br />

to the st<strong>and</strong>ard curriculum of university<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>-house tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g.<br />

• Bus<strong>in</strong>ess access to know-how <strong>and</strong><br />

capital <strong>for</strong> implement<strong>in</strong>g the potentials<br />

via contract<strong>in</strong>g or other risk-benefitshar<strong>in</strong>g<br />

schemes with third parties is<br />

hampered by lack<strong>in</strong>g modularization of<br />

production systems as well as miss<strong>in</strong>g<br />

practicable st<strong>and</strong>ards <strong>for</strong> respective<br />

contracts <strong>and</strong> measur<strong>in</strong>g procedures.<br />

However, most of these barriers can be<br />

removed by economic policy action <strong>in</strong> conjunction<br />

with s<strong>in</strong>gle-company measures.<br />

By support<strong>in</strong>g respective media reports<br />

the government can foster an awareness<br />

<strong>for</strong> the extent of material <strong>through</strong>put costs<br />

<strong>and</strong> ways of <strong>in</strong>fluenc<strong>in</strong>g them. It can ac-<br />

2


celerate the spread of best practice with<br />

special support programmes. Moreover,<br />

via its own procurement <strong>and</strong> by improv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

consumer <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation with regard to life<br />

cycle cost it can enhance market access<br />

<strong>and</strong> the spread of profitable dematerialised<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> services. And the government<br />

can make sure that every university<br />

graduate is <strong>in</strong> comm<strong>and</strong> of the ABC of<br />

dematerialization <strong>in</strong> his or her profession.<br />

The Question at Issue<br />

If economic policy is to commit itself to<br />

support<strong>in</strong>g profitable dematerialization<br />

then a pre-quantification of atta<strong>in</strong>able economic<br />

results is expedient. To this end the<br />

Aachen Foundation Kathy Beys – whose<br />

focus of work is dematerialization – has<br />

commissioned a study whose results are<br />

presented <strong>in</strong> this paper.<br />

The question at issue of this study is:<br />

What effects upon private sector turnover,<br />

employment <strong>and</strong> public budgets arise if<br />

the observable s<strong>in</strong>gle-company efficiency<br />

reserves of profitable dematerialization are<br />

widely implemented <strong>in</strong> the national economy?<br />

Scientific appraisals of the macroeconomic<br />

effects of profitable dematerialization are<br />

not yet available <strong>in</strong> Germany as far as the<br />

authors are aware.<br />

With regard to the similar processes of<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle-company cost-neutral dematerialization<br />

as well as profitable reduction of<br />

cost factors other than material <strong>through</strong>put<br />

selected exist<strong>in</strong>g appraisals are summarised<br />

below.<br />

Appraisals of S<strong>in</strong>gle-Company Cost-<br />

Neutral Dematerialization<br />

In a study commissioned by Greenpeace,<br />

the Prognos AG 5 exam<strong>in</strong>ed the effects on<br />

employment <strong>and</strong> growth of a s<strong>in</strong>glecompany<br />

cost-neutral dematerialization<br />

<strong>through</strong> a shift of goods <strong>and</strong> services from<br />

material-<strong>in</strong>tensive to less material<strong>in</strong>tensive<br />

<strong>for</strong>ms of production or sectors.<br />

5 Prognos AG, Mehr Arbeitsplätze durch ökologisches<br />

Wirtschaften? E<strong>in</strong>e Untersuchung für<br />

Deutschl<strong>and</strong>, die Schweiz und Österreich, Gutachten<br />

im Auftrag von Greenpeace, Hamburg 1999.<br />

For <strong>in</strong>stance, a shift of agricultural production<br />

from conventional to biological farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> a shift of transport from private to public<br />

transport was modelled. The effects <strong>for</strong><br />

the year 2020 <strong>in</strong> Germany, Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> Austria were assessed us<strong>in</strong>g a comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

bottom-up <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>put-output model.<br />

In sum, a reduction of material <strong>in</strong>put by<br />

25% as well as of non-renewable energy<br />

sources by 30% <strong>in</strong> 2020 aga<strong>in</strong>st the basel<strong>in</strong>e<br />

of 1990 led to slightly positive employment<br />

effects <strong>in</strong> all three national<br />

economies studied. For Germany the net<br />

employment effect was over 160,000 new<br />

jobs. Modell<strong>in</strong>g came up with a neutral<br />

effect on the gross domestic product<br />

(GDP) of all three countries.<br />

Meyer <strong>and</strong> Lutz 6 analysed the effects of<br />

the <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>put quota observable between<br />

1980 <strong>and</strong> 1990 <strong>in</strong> so-called “other<br />

market-determ<strong>in</strong>ed services”, a heterogeneous<br />

group <strong>in</strong> which, amongst others,<br />

consultancy companies, eng<strong>in</strong>eer<strong>in</strong>g companies,<br />

advertis<strong>in</strong>g agencies <strong>and</strong> clean<strong>in</strong>g<br />

companies are merged. The effects are<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ed by a comparison of actual developments<br />

with simulated scenarios <strong>in</strong> a<br />

complex econometric Pantha Rhei model<br />

that consists of about 50,000 equations, is<br />

deeply disaggregated by sector <strong>and</strong><br />

whose parameters have been estimated<br />

econometrically on the basis of developments<br />

between 1978 <strong>and</strong> 1994. One of<br />

these scenarios describes de facto the<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease of material <strong>in</strong>put by 10% with a<br />

concomitant identical <strong>in</strong>put reduction value<br />

<strong>in</strong> “other market-determ<strong>in</strong>ed services”.<br />

This cost-neutral deterioration of material<br />

efficiency reduces GDP <strong>in</strong> the 1980-1990<br />

time span by 2.3% <strong>and</strong> the wage bill by<br />

2.4% with a slight <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> employment<br />

growth (0.2%).<br />

These results suggest s<strong>in</strong>gle-company<br />

cost-neutral dematerialization can achieve<br />

clearly positive effects upon GDP <strong>and</strong> the<br />

wage bill while only slightly positive or<br />

negative employment effects. Similar re-<br />

6 Meyer, B. <strong>and</strong> C. Lutz, Ökoeffiziente Dienstleistungen<br />

und Materialverbrauch. E<strong>in</strong>e Simulationsstudie<br />

mit dem disaggregierten Modell PHANTA RHEI,<br />

<strong>in</strong> H<strong>in</strong>terhuber, F. <strong>and</strong> H. Schnabl (eds.), Arbeit –<br />

Umwelt – Wachstum. Nachhaltigkeitsaspekte des<br />

sektoralen Strukturw<strong>and</strong>els, Norderstedt 2002, pp.<br />

190-228.<br />

3


sults are on h<strong>and</strong> with respect to appraisals<br />

of the national economic effects of<br />

programmes designed to <strong>in</strong>crease energy<br />

efficiency 7 .<br />

Appraisals of <strong>Profitable</strong> Productivity<br />

Increases <strong>in</strong> S<strong>in</strong>gle-Companies<br />

Material sav<strong>in</strong>gs can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as a<br />

k<strong>in</strong>d of cost reduction that leads to <strong>in</strong>creased<br />

productivity. A dematerialization<br />

of the economy has similar effects on employment<br />

as productivity <strong>in</strong>creases. An<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> productivity 8 <strong>in</strong> turn is led primarily<br />

by product <strong>and</strong> process <strong>in</strong>novation.<br />

An abundance of empirical literature is<br />

available on this topic 9 . There are three<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> conclusions.<br />

• Many analyses 10 <strong>for</strong> Germany come to<br />

the conclusion that process <strong>in</strong>novation<br />

leads to employment losses. While<br />

7 Cf. <strong>for</strong> example Bach, S. <strong>and</strong> C. Bork, M. Kohlhaas,<br />

C. Lutz, B. Meyer, B. Preatorius, H. Welsch,<br />

Die ökologische Steuerre<strong>for</strong>m <strong>in</strong> Deutschl<strong>and</strong>. E<strong>in</strong>e<br />

modellgestützte Analyse ihrer Wirkungen auf Wirtschaft<br />

und Umwelt, Berl<strong>in</strong> 2001; Barker, T., Achiev<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a 10 per cent cut <strong>in</strong> Europe’s CO2 emissions<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g aditional excise duties: multilateral versus<br />

unilateral action E3ME, E3ME Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No.<br />

29, Vienna 1998; Böhr<strong>in</strong>ger, C., <strong>and</strong> H. Welsch, A.<br />

Löschel, Environmental Taxation <strong>and</strong> Structural<br />

Change <strong>in</strong> an Open Economy – A CGE Analysis<br />

with Imperfect Competition <strong>and</strong> Free Entry, ZEW<br />

Discussion Paper No. 01-07, Mannheim2001;<br />

RWI/Ifo (eds.), Gesamtwirtschaftliche Beurteilung<br />

von CO2-M<strong>in</strong>derungsstrategien, Untersuchungen<br />

des Rhe<strong>in</strong>isch-Westfälischen Instituts für Wirtschafts<strong>for</strong>schung,<br />

Issue 19, Essen 1996.<br />

8 The OECD provides a good overview <strong>in</strong>: Organisation<br />

<strong>for</strong> Economic Co-operation <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

(OECD) (ed.), The Sources of Economic <strong>Growth</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

OECD Countries, Paris 2003.<br />

9 For a broad overview see: Lehner, F. <strong>and</strong> M.<br />

Baethge, J. Kühl, F. Stille (eds.), Beschäftigung<br />

durch Innovation, Munich 1998. Or <strong>for</strong> a shorter<br />

compilation see: Beeker, D., Technischer Fortschritt<br />

und Beschäftigung, Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft<br />

Köln, Beiträge zur Wirtschafts- und Sozialpolitik, No.<br />

264, Cologne 2001.<br />

10 Rottmann, H. <strong>and</strong> M. Rusch<strong>in</strong>ski, The Labour<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Innovation Behaviour of Firms,<br />

Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik,<br />

Volume 217 (1998), pp. 741-752; or: Blech<strong>in</strong>ger, D.<br />

<strong>and</strong> F. Pfeiffer, Qualifikation, Beschäftigung und<br />

technischer Fortschritt, Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie<br />

und Statistik, Volume 218 (1999), pp. 128-<br />

146; also: Flaig, G. <strong>and</strong> H. Rottmann, Faktorpreise,<br />

technischer Fortschritt und Beschäftigung, E<strong>in</strong>e<br />

empirische Analyse für das westdeutsche verarbeitende<br />

Gewerbe, ifo-Diskussionsbeitrag No. 59,<br />

Munich 1998.<br />

Bellmann/Kohaut 11 do not come to<br />

clear conclusions, other studies 12 show<br />

a positive correlation. A more detailed<br />

comparison of analyses shows that a<br />

positive <strong>in</strong>fluence of process <strong>in</strong>novations<br />

on employment is more likely to<br />

occur if many secondary compensatory<br />

effects (price reductions, quality<br />

improvements, <strong>in</strong>vestment growth,<br />

wage reductions etc.) are considered.<br />

This is a very plausible f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g. On the<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle-company level rationalisation<br />

measures lead to employment losses,<br />

at least <strong>in</strong> the short term. Viewed from<br />

a national economic <strong>and</strong> medium term<br />

perspective a different picture emerges<br />

because released personnel can aga<strong>in</strong><br />

f<strong>in</strong>d productive employment.<br />

• The situation with respect to product<br />

<strong>in</strong>novation is different. Here, most<br />

studies show a positive correlation between<br />

<strong>in</strong>novation, i.e. productivity <strong>in</strong>creases,<br />

<strong>and</strong> employment.<br />

The INFORGE Model<br />

The national economic effects of dematerialization<br />

are so complex that they can<br />

only be mean<strong>in</strong>gfully captured <strong>and</strong> empirically<br />

measured us<strong>in</strong>g a model. For that<br />

purpose the INFORGE (INter<strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

FORcast<strong>in</strong>g GErmany) model is used.<br />

INFORGE is a profoundly structured sectoral<br />

<strong>for</strong>ecast<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> simulation model that<br />

has been updated annually s<strong>in</strong>ce 1996<br />

<strong>and</strong> used <strong>in</strong> many applications 13 . The ver-<br />

11 Bellmann, L. <strong>and</strong> S. Kohaut, Betriebliche Beschäftigungsentwicklung<br />

und Innovationsaktivitäten, <strong>in</strong>:<br />

Mitteilungen IAB, Volume 32 (1999), pp. 416-422.<br />

12 Almus, M. <strong>and</strong> E. Nehrl<strong>in</strong>ger, Beschäftigungsdynamik<br />

<strong>in</strong> jungen <strong>in</strong>novativen Unternehmen: Empirische<br />

Ergebnisse für West-Deutschl<strong>and</strong>, Diskussionspapier<br />

No. 98-09, Zentrum für Europäische<br />

Wirtschafts<strong>for</strong>schung, Mannheim 1998; or Smolny,<br />

W. <strong>and</strong> T. Schneeweis, Innovation, Wachstum und<br />

Beschäftigung, E<strong>in</strong>e empirische Untersuchung auf<br />

der Basis des ifo-Unternehmenspanels Center <strong>for</strong><br />

International Labour Economics, Forschungsschwerpunkt<br />

„Internationale Arbeitsmarkt<strong>for</strong>schung“,<br />

Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften und Statistik,<br />

Discussion Paper 33-1996, Konstanz.<br />

13 Cf. <strong>for</strong> example: Lichtblau, K. <strong>and</strong> B. Meyer, G.<br />

Ewerhart, Komplementäres Beziehungsgeflecht<br />

zwischen Industrie und Dienstleistungen, <strong>in</strong>: iwtrends,<br />

4/96, pp. 1-24; or: Elixmann, D. <strong>and</strong> A. Keuter,<br />

B. Meyer, Sectoral <strong>Employment</strong> Effects of the<br />

Evolution of the German Telecommunications Mar-<br />

4


sion used <strong>in</strong> this paper is based on the<br />

German Federal Agency <strong>for</strong> Statistic’s new<br />

NACE classification of national account<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

INFORGE is the economic part of the<br />

Panta Rhei model that has proved itself as<br />

an <strong>in</strong>strument <strong>for</strong> the analysis of environmental-economic<br />

relationships 14 .<br />

The INFORGE model’s strong per<strong>for</strong>mance<br />

potential is based on the INFORUM<br />

philosophy 15 that is characterised by the<br />

bottom-up <strong>and</strong> complete <strong>in</strong>tegration construction<br />

pr<strong>in</strong>ciples. The bottom-up construction<br />

pr<strong>in</strong>ciple says that each of the 59<br />

sectors of the national economy is modelled<br />

<strong>in</strong> great detail <strong>and</strong> that the national<br />

economic variables are <strong>for</strong>mulated <strong>through</strong><br />

explicit aggregation with<strong>in</strong> the model. The<br />

construction pr<strong>in</strong>ciple complete <strong>in</strong>tegration<br />

consists of a complex <strong>and</strong> simultaneous<br />

modell<strong>in</strong>g that depicts <strong>in</strong>ter-<strong>in</strong>dustrial l<strong>in</strong>kages<br />

as well as the development <strong>and</strong> distribution<br />

of <strong>in</strong>come, the government’s redistribution<br />

actions <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>come use by<br />

private households <strong>for</strong> various goods <strong>and</strong><br />

services.<br />

ket, 1996-2005, <strong>in</strong>: Communication Strategies, No.<br />

28, 4th Quarter 1997, pp. 105-127; or: Meyer, B.<br />

<strong>and</strong> G. Ewerhart, Lohnsatz, Produktivität und Beschäftigung.<br />

Ergebnisse e<strong>in</strong>er Simulationsstudie mit<br />

dem disaggregierten ökonometrischen Modell<br />

INFORGE, <strong>in</strong>: Schnabl, H. (ed.), Innovation und<br />

Arbeit: Fakten – Analysen – Perspektiven, Tüb<strong>in</strong>gen<br />

1997, pp. 253-267; or: Meyer, B. <strong>and</strong> G. Ewerhart,<br />

T. Siebe, Strukturw<strong>and</strong>el, Arbeitsplätze und dienstleistungen.<br />

Analyse des sektoralen Strukturw<strong>and</strong>els<br />

<strong>in</strong> der Beschäftigung des IHK-Bezirks Münster für<br />

die Jahre 1978 bis 1996 und Prognose bis zum Jahr<br />

2000, Expertise commissioned by the Münster<br />

Chamber of Trade <strong>and</strong> Commerce, 1998; or: Meyer,<br />

B. <strong>and</strong> G. Ewerhart, T. Siebe, Tertiarisierung ohne<br />

wettbewerbsfähige Industriebasis?, <strong>in</strong>: Raum<strong>for</strong>schung<br />

und Raumordnung, No. 5/6-99; or: Meyer,<br />

B. <strong>and</strong> G. Ahlert, Die ökonomischen Perspektiven<br />

des Sports. E<strong>in</strong>e empirische Analyse für die Bundesrepublik<br />

Deutschl<strong>and</strong>, Schriftenreihe des Bundes<strong>in</strong>stituts<br />

für Sportwissenschaft, Volume 100,<br />

Schorndorf 2000; or: Lutz, C. <strong>and</strong> B. Meyer, P.<br />

Schnur, G. Zika, Projektion des Arbeitskräftebedarfs<br />

bis 2015. Modellrechnungen auf Basis des<br />

IAB/INFORGE-Modells, <strong>in</strong>: Mitteilungen aus der<br />

Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufs<strong>for</strong>schung (MittIAB),<br />

3/2002, pp. 305-326.<br />

14 Frohn, J. <strong>and</strong> P. Chen, B. Hillebr<strong>and</strong>, W. Lemke,<br />

C. Lutz, B. Meyer, M. Pullen, Wirkungen umweltpolitischer<br />

Maßnahmen. Abschätzungen mit zwei ökonometrischen<br />

Modellen, Heidelberg 2003.<br />

15 Almon, C., The INFORUM-approach to Inter<strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

Modell<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>: Economic Systems Research<br />

3, 1991, pp. 1-7.<br />

The disaggregated structure of the<br />

INFORGE model is reflected <strong>in</strong> an enormous<br />

but consistent <strong>in</strong><strong>for</strong>mation process<strong>in</strong>g:<br />

The nearly 40,000 model equations<br />

are embedded <strong>in</strong> the fully endogenised<br />

account system of national economic account<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

The model is characterised by a<br />

very high degree of endogenisation. Exogenously<br />

specified are primarily only a few<br />

tax rates, labour supply <strong>and</strong> the global<br />

market variables of the <strong>in</strong>ternational<br />

GLODYM system that is an enhancement<br />

of the global COMPASS model 16 .<br />

INFORGE is an econometric <strong>in</strong>put-output<br />

model that can be described as an evolutionary<br />

model 17 . The behavioural equations<br />

model decision-mak<strong>in</strong>g rout<strong>in</strong>es that<br />

are not explicitly <strong>in</strong>terpreted from the optimisation<br />

behaviour of agents but are<br />

based on limited rationality. Prices are<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> terms of monopolised pricesett<strong>in</strong>g<br />

behaviour. The model describes<br />

time as historical <strong>and</strong> irreversible. Capital<br />

adjustment generates path <strong>in</strong>dependence.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>put-output approach is commonly<br />

viewed as dem<strong>and</strong>-oriented modell<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

However, this is not the case <strong>for</strong><br />

INFORGE. Even if it is true that dem<strong>and</strong><br />

determ<strong>in</strong>es production <strong>in</strong> INFORGE, all<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> factor dem<strong>and</strong> variables depend<br />

upon, amongst other th<strong>in</strong>gs, relative<br />

prices, whereby the prices themselves are<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ed by companies’ unit costs <strong>in</strong><br />

terms of a price-sett<strong>in</strong>g hypothesis. In this<br />

case, the difference vis-à-vis general balance<br />

models, <strong>in</strong> which a competitive market<br />

is modelled, is <strong>in</strong> the implicit market<br />

<strong>for</strong>m, not <strong>in</strong> the emphasis of one or the<br />

other side of the market. In other words,<br />

companies choose their sales price on the<br />

basis of their cost situation <strong>and</strong> the prices<br />

of compet<strong>in</strong>g imports. Dem<strong>and</strong> reacts to<br />

this with a decision that then determ<strong>in</strong>es<br />

the amount of production. In this way,<br />

supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> elements are equally<br />

prevalent.<br />

16 Meyer, B. <strong>and</strong> K. Uno, COMPASS – E<strong>in</strong> globales<br />

Energie-Wirtschafts-modell, <strong>in</strong> : ifo-Studien, No. 45,<br />

1999, pp. 703-718. Meyer, B. <strong>and</strong> C. Lutz, Ökoeffiziente<br />

Dienstleistungen…, l.c.<br />

17 Meyer, B., Strukturanalyse, <strong>in</strong>: Herrmann-Pillath,<br />

C. <strong>and</strong> M. Lehmann-Waffenschmidt (eds.), H<strong>and</strong>buch<br />

Evolutorische Ökonomie, Berl<strong>in</strong> 2003.<br />

5


Besides the level of <strong>in</strong>put-output computation<br />

that is profoundly structured <strong>in</strong> 59 production<br />

or economic sectors, the model <strong>for</strong><br />

the computation of the national economic<br />

variables conta<strong>in</strong>s the account system of<br />

the national economic accounts of the<br />

Federal Republic of Germany. This system<br />

conta<strong>in</strong>s all <strong>in</strong>come redistribution <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g<br />

social security <strong>and</strong> taxation between the<br />

government, private households <strong>and</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus enables the computation of<br />

available <strong>in</strong>comes which themselves are<br />

important determ<strong>in</strong>ants of f<strong>in</strong>al dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Moreover, the f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g balances of <strong>in</strong>stitutional<br />

transactors are determ<strong>in</strong>ed. This<br />

means that governmental budget restrictions<br />

are also <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the model. The<br />

complete fiscal policy is there<strong>for</strong>e also<br />

endogenously embedded <strong>in</strong> the system.<br />

Monetary policy, <strong>in</strong> as much as it <strong>in</strong>fluences<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest levels, is also endogenous.<br />

Scenarios Exam<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

The period 2004-2015 was chosen <strong>for</strong> the<br />

appraisal as this is an appropriate time l<strong>in</strong>e<br />

<strong>for</strong> a political programme that seeks to<br />

change efficiency structures on a wide<br />

scale <strong>in</strong> the economy at large. The effects<br />

of profitable dematerialization are exam<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

by us<strong>in</strong>g the values achieved <strong>in</strong> 2015<br />

on the basis of different scenarios <strong>and</strong><br />

compar<strong>in</strong>g them to the zero variant (endogenous<br />

extrapolation of the status quo<br />

<strong>in</strong> the model):<br />

• In Scenario I “Imperfect Markets” profitable<br />

dematerialization takes place<br />

with<strong>in</strong> the environment of present-day<br />

wage <strong>and</strong> price <strong>for</strong>mation <strong>in</strong> Germany.<br />

• In Scenario II “Wage Competition” it is<br />

assumed – <strong>in</strong> variance to Scenario I –<br />

that productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>through</strong> dematerialization<br />

do not lead to higher wages<br />

but <strong>in</strong>stead correspond to those of the<br />

base scenario.<br />

• In Scenario III “Price Competition” we<br />

assume – <strong>in</strong> variance to Scenario I –<br />

that competitive pressure <strong>for</strong>ces companies<br />

to pass on nationally achieved<br />

productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s to consumers <strong>in</strong> the<br />

<strong>for</strong>m of lower prices. Wage <strong>for</strong>mation<br />

corresponds to that <strong>in</strong> Scenario I.<br />

Scenarios II <strong>and</strong> III do not confer with present-day<br />

economic practice but po<strong>in</strong>t to<br />

the numerous welfare ga<strong>in</strong>s that can be<br />

achieved on the labour <strong>and</strong> product markets<br />

on the basis of more complete competition.<br />

Common Assumptions<br />

Across all Scenarios<br />

Simplified assumptions are necessary <strong>for</strong><br />

depict<strong>in</strong>g the scenarios <strong>in</strong> INFORGE. In all<br />

scenarios, profitable dematerialization is<br />

depicted <strong>through</strong> a l<strong>in</strong>ear reduction of material<br />

costs per unit of production <strong>in</strong> the<br />

manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> public adm<strong>in</strong>istration<br />

by 20% across the study’s time<br />

l<strong>in</strong>e. In several ways, this is a conservative<br />

assumption:<br />

• Company practice shows double as<br />

much potential (20% of manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

costs <strong>in</strong>stead of 20% of material<br />

costs).<br />

• The scenarios limit the cost effects to<br />

production <strong>in</strong> the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> public adm<strong>in</strong>istration. This<br />

means that the economic sectors with<br />

the highest dematerialization potentials<br />

are addressed but that a political programme<br />

aimed at profitable<br />

dematerialization will have effects on<br />

other sectors too <strong>through</strong> respectively<br />

optimised products <strong>and</strong> know-how<br />

• transfer. The development of new products is<br />

not explicitly taken <strong>in</strong>to account <strong>in</strong> the<br />

scenarios. In reality, however, a strong<br />

surge toward the dematerialization of<br />

production <strong>and</strong> product use will not<br />

only reduce costs but also create new<br />

products. Cellular phones are a case <strong>in</strong><br />

po<strong>in</strong>t which only became a mass market<br />

after m<strong>in</strong>iaturisation with concomitant<br />

cost reductions <strong>and</strong> easier usability<br />

occurred.<br />

As such efficiency ga<strong>in</strong>s do not simply fall<br />

from the heavens but require <strong>in</strong>novation<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment by companies annual sav<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

need to be juxtaposed with one-time<br />

expenditures 33% of which consist of dem<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>for</strong> services close to the company<br />

<strong>and</strong> 66% of which consist of fixed <strong>in</strong>vestment.<br />

With respect to material cost reduction<br />

(50% of total <strong>in</strong>dustrial costs) this onetime<br />

expenditure amounts to a simple annual<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>g while with respect to energy<br />

cost reduction (2% of <strong>in</strong>dustrial costs) it<br />

6


amounts to a sixfold annual sav<strong>in</strong>g. These<br />

figures are based on consultancy experience<br />

as well as empirical research 18 .<br />

Description <strong>and</strong><br />

Interpretation of Results<br />

Initially, dematerialization has two direct<br />

effects. For one, it reduces costs <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> public adm<strong>in</strong>istration.<br />

For another, it reduces turnover of<br />

material suppliers who are <strong>in</strong> turn ma<strong>in</strong>ly<br />

located <strong>in</strong> the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector. So<br />

there will be w<strong>in</strong>ners <strong>and</strong> losers of dematerialization.<br />

Cost reductions have numerous <strong>in</strong>direct<br />

effects whose most important correlations<br />

are depicted schematically <strong>in</strong> figure 1. Initially,<br />

cost reduction has the effect of reduc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

prices. If price reductions are lower<br />

than cost reductions, which is usually the<br />

case, bus<strong>in</strong>ess profits will <strong>in</strong>crease. This<br />

leads to <strong>in</strong>creased fiscal <strong>in</strong>come on the<br />

part of the government <strong>and</strong> higher private<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come. Both effects <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> goods <strong>and</strong> services <strong>and</strong> there<strong>for</strong>e<br />

turnover, production <strong>and</strong> employment.<br />

On a purely calculative basis a growth of<br />

company profit means that companies’<br />

added value per employee <strong>in</strong>creases, socalled<br />

labour productivity. Together with<br />

price development, this is an equally important<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>for</strong> wages. The price<br />

reduction effected by dematerialization<br />

squeezes down wages, whereas the<br />

growth <strong>in</strong> labour productivity exp<strong>and</strong>s<br />

wages. As productivity <strong>in</strong>crease – as will<br />

be shown below – is stronger than price<br />

decl<strong>in</strong>e we have an on balance wage <strong>in</strong>crease.<br />

The effects on employment cannot be<br />

clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed. The production growth<br />

depicted above <strong>in</strong>creases employment. On<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong> we have just established<br />

that wage rates <strong>in</strong>crease. If we <strong>in</strong>clude the<br />

general decl<strong>in</strong>e of prices we have a clear<br />

growth of real wages with negative effects<br />

upon employment. Then, we will also have<br />

tangential effects on <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

18 Cf. <strong>for</strong> example Prognos AG, Klimaschutz und<br />

Arbeitsplätze – s<strong>in</strong>d klimaschützende Maßnahmen<br />

e<strong>in</strong> s<strong>in</strong>nvoller Beitrag zur Arbeitsmarktpolitik?,<br />

Frankfurt 2001.<br />

Interpretation of Scenario I<br />

(Imperfect Markets)<br />

The results correlate with theoretical considerations<br />

as they have just been discussed<br />

above (see figure 1). Productivity<br />

ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>duce GDP growth <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g usage<br />

components (see table 1). Real GDP <strong>in</strong><br />

2015 is 10.5% above the respective figure<br />

<strong>in</strong> the base-l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>for</strong>ecast. This correlates to<br />

absolute changes <strong>in</strong> 2015 vis-à-vis the<br />

base-l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>for</strong>ecast <strong>for</strong> the:<br />

• Economy. Turnover is EUR 152.4 billion<br />

higher <strong>in</strong> stable prices, net company<br />

profit grows <strong>in</strong> respective prices<br />

by EUR 172.9 billion.<br />

• Employees: Wage bills are nom<strong>in</strong>ally<br />

higher at EUR 74.6 billion.<br />

• Public sector budgets: We have a relief<br />

of about EUR 1.3 billion.<br />

Consumption, <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>and</strong> exports<br />

also show <strong>in</strong>creases. Imports are slightly<br />

reduced due to a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> specific advance<br />

<strong>in</strong>put dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> an improved<br />

competitive position of German companies<br />

despite GDP growth.<br />

In sum, these results show that profitable<br />

dematerialization corresponds to welfare<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> the <strong>for</strong>m of a higher social<br />

product <strong>and</strong> an even higher growth of real<br />

7


private consumption. If we subtract consumer<br />

goods prices (1.8%) from the relative<br />

change <strong>in</strong> the wage rate (6.5%) we get<br />

an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the real wage rate that is<br />

8.3% higher than the base-l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>for</strong>ecast:<br />

An hourly wage can then purchase 8.2%<br />

more consumer goods. An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong><br />

material efficiency apparently makes the<br />

national economy wealthier.<br />

Table 1<br />

Effects of Dematerialization as Devia-<br />

tions to the Base-L<strong>in</strong>e Forecast <strong>in</strong> 2015<br />

Variable Scenario I<br />

“Perfect<br />

Markets”<br />

Consumer<br />

goods prices<br />

Producer<br />

costs<br />

Labour<br />

productivity<br />

<strong>in</strong> stable<br />

prices<br />

Production<br />

value<br />

Gross domestic<br />

product<br />

Private<br />

consumption<br />

State consumption<br />

Capital<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

Construction<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

Scenario II<br />

“Wage<br />

Competition”<br />

Scenario<br />

III<br />

“Price<br />

Competition”<br />

relative deviation <strong>in</strong> per cent<br />

-1.87 -3,25 -7.17<br />

-1.29 -2.55 -7.49<br />

6.52 0.29 4.00<br />

3.30 2.38 6.41<br />

10.48 9.37 13.83<br />

13.36 10.96 15.44<br />

5.98 5.20 11.41<br />

3.71 3.33 5.95<br />

3.25 2.87 4.44<br />

Exports 0.69 0.71 2.20<br />

Imports -2.07 -3.16 -2.50<br />

<strong>in</strong> respective<br />

prices<br />

State f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

balance<br />

absolute deviations <strong>in</strong> Euro (billions)<br />

1.28 21.24 -5.72<br />

<strong>in</strong> persons absolute deviations <strong>in</strong> persons<br />

Employees<br />

(rounded to<br />

10,000)<br />

-480,000 760,000 -300,000<br />

The government profits from dematerialization<br />

<strong>in</strong> two ways. For one, it is a direct<br />

beneficiary because costs <strong>in</strong> public adm<strong>in</strong>istration<br />

fall by nearly EUR 3 billion<br />

annually <strong>through</strong> a reduction <strong>in</strong> material<br />

costs. For another, it profits from general<br />

economic development. However, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

fiscal <strong>in</strong>come is counteracted by higher<br />

social costs <strong>through</strong> lower employment so<br />

that the f<strong>in</strong>ancial balance of the government<br />

improves only relatively marg<strong>in</strong>ally at<br />

EUR 1.3 billion.<br />

Several important results of Scenario I<br />

require further <strong>in</strong>terpretation:<br />

• Despite the acceleration of economic<br />

growth the number of ga<strong>in</strong>fully employed<br />

persons is about 480.000 lower<br />

<strong>in</strong> 2015 than <strong>in</strong> the base-l<strong>in</strong>e <strong>for</strong>ecast.<br />

• In Scenario I the production costs <strong>for</strong><br />

German companies <strong>in</strong> the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

sector fall by about 10%. Consumer<br />

goods prices – which encompass<br />

products of the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>and</strong> services sectors – decl<strong>in</strong>e by only<br />

1.8%. This discrepancy cannot only be<br />

attributed to the fact that dematerialization<br />

<strong>in</strong> the simulation model is limited<br />

to the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector. Rather, it<br />

is also attributed to market imperfections.<br />

How can employment fall despite the<br />

stated general economic upturn? First of<br />

all we should not <strong>for</strong>get that – as elaborated<br />

above – one direct effect of dematerialization<br />

on employment is negative.<br />

Namely, that producers of material are<br />

afflicted by a drop <strong>in</strong> turnover <strong>and</strong> employment.<br />

Even if other companies do enjoy<br />

cost reductions as well as profit from<br />

an <strong>in</strong>creased dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>for</strong> goods, which<br />

has positive effects <strong>for</strong> employment, this is<br />

counteracted by the wage <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>duced<br />

by productivity growth as described<br />

above. This effect corresponds to the<br />

wage <strong>for</strong>mulation that is a reality of the<br />

German labour market. Moreover, these<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs are <strong>in</strong> alignment with f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs presented<br />

<strong>in</strong> the literature outl<strong>in</strong>ed above,<br />

namely that process <strong>in</strong>novation tends to<br />

lead to employment losses.<br />

Results of Scenario II<br />

However, it is also possible to envision a<br />

wage <strong>for</strong>mulation that takes place <strong>in</strong> the<br />

framework of a societal consensus <strong>in</strong>dependently<br />

of the productivity growth <strong>in</strong>duced<br />

by dematerialization. Wage <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

then correspond to those depicted<br />

<strong>in</strong> the base-l<strong>in</strong>e scenario. All other assumptions<br />

rema<strong>in</strong> unchanged.<br />

8


Table 1 shows that the effects on GDP are<br />

only slightly different to those <strong>in</strong> Scenario<br />

I. However, this scenario has a much better<br />

labour market effect of about 760,000<br />

additional jobs because the negative effect<br />

on employment due to wage <strong>in</strong>creases is<br />

<strong>in</strong>applicable.<br />

Further results of Scenario II <strong>in</strong> 2015 <strong>in</strong><br />

comparison to the base-l<strong>in</strong>e scenario are:<br />

• Economy: Real production value grows<br />

by 2.4% or EUR 110.0 billion, net<br />

company profits grow nom<strong>in</strong>ally by<br />

EUR 163.6 billion.<br />

• Employees: The wage bill grows nom<strong>in</strong>ally<br />

by merely EUR 22.3 billion. However,<br />

prices fall more than <strong>in</strong> Scenario I<br />

with the effect of a real improvement of<br />

the position of employees:<br />

With practically unchanged nom<strong>in</strong>al<br />

wages real wages <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>through</strong> a<br />

3% decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> consumer prices while<br />

employment <strong>in</strong>creases by about<br />

756,000 persons.<br />

• Public sector budgets: Relief at a<br />

nom<strong>in</strong>al EUR 21.2 billion is now considerably<br />

higher than <strong>in</strong> Scenario I because<br />

social costs are now much lower<br />

due to the employment situation.<br />

Of course, employment effects do not take<br />

place to the same degree across all sectors,<br />

as figure 2 shows. Def<strong>in</strong>ite w<strong>in</strong>ners<br />

can be found <strong>in</strong> all service sectors. Besides<br />

trade <strong>and</strong> services close to companies,<br />

the health sector, education, culture,<br />

sports <strong>and</strong> enterta<strong>in</strong>ment as well home<br />

services benefit particularly. These sectors<br />

profit from an <strong>in</strong>creased dem<strong>and</strong> emanat-<br />

<strong>in</strong>g from higher <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>in</strong>duced by dematerialization.<br />

Results of Scenario III<br />

In Scenario III productivity growth m<strong>in</strong>us<br />

the counteract<strong>in</strong>g wage development is<br />

passed on fully to consumers <strong>in</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of<br />

price reductions. With respect to wage<br />

<strong>for</strong>mulation we assume the same behaviour<br />

as <strong>in</strong> Scenario I. This means that the<br />

wage rate is endogenous.<br />

The benefit <strong>for</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess, employees <strong>and</strong><br />

the government is <strong>in</strong>itially <strong>in</strong> a clear improvement<br />

of purchas<strong>in</strong>g power vis-à-vis<br />

Scenario I <strong>and</strong> II because of a price reduction<br />

of 7.2%. The expansive effect on GDP<br />

is the strongest of all scenarios. In comparison<br />

to the base-l<strong>in</strong>e scenario the follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

effects are anticipated <strong>for</strong> 2015:<br />

• Economy: Production value <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

<strong>in</strong> real terms by 6.4% or EUR 195.5 billion,<br />

net company profit <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

nom<strong>in</strong>ally by EUR 115.0 billion.<br />

• Employee wages: The wage bill <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

by a nom<strong>in</strong>al EUR 38.6 billion,<br />

purchas<strong>in</strong>g power per work<strong>in</strong>g hour <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

by 11.2% concomitant with a<br />

7.2% decrease <strong>in</strong> consumer goods<br />

prices <strong>and</strong> a 4.0% <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> nom<strong>in</strong>al<br />

wage rates. However, employment<br />

drops by about 300,000 persons due<br />

to the strong growth <strong>in</strong> real wages.<br />

<strong>Employment</strong> losses are much lower<br />

than <strong>in</strong> Scenario I because of the<br />

stronger general economic upturn.<br />

• Public sector budgets: In comparison<br />

to Scenario II the state budget is burdened<br />

by higher social costs so that<br />

the effect on the f<strong>in</strong>ancial balance of<br />

the state at EUR -5.7% billion is<br />

slightly negative.<br />

This means that stronger price competition<br />

<strong>in</strong> the national market also <strong>in</strong>creases the<br />

benefits of a profitable dematerialization<br />

<strong>and</strong> other productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>for</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>esses,<br />

the state <strong>and</strong> employees as well<br />

as provid<strong>in</strong>g a limited number of new jobs.<br />

9


Summary of Results<br />

Computations with the econometric<br />

INFORGE model have shown that a profitable<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease of material efficiency on a<br />

s<strong>in</strong>gle-company basis leads to overall productivity<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>and</strong> price reductions <strong>in</strong><br />

the national economy which foster economic<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> have positive effects on<br />

real <strong>in</strong>come <strong>for</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>and</strong> private<br />

households. Due to imperfect goods’ markets<br />

these price reductions are lower than<br />

the productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s.<br />

If wage rates <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> accordance with<br />

this productivity growth a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> employment<br />

would occur despite the real <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

<strong>in</strong> GDP. But if wage rates follow<br />

the paths they would have taken without<br />

dematerialization then we would witness<br />

clear employment growth.<br />

Closely l<strong>in</strong>ked thereto are the effects on<br />

the state budget. Depend<strong>in</strong>g on how the<br />

wage rate reacts there are negative or<br />

positive effects upon the f<strong>in</strong>ancial balance<br />

of the social security system that clearly<br />

outweigh the direct effects of profitable<br />

dematerialization on public sector spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

The effects of the profitable <strong>in</strong>crease of<br />

material efficiency modelled here on the<br />

labour market <strong>and</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ancial balance of<br />

the state there<strong>for</strong>e depend on the concrete<br />

design of dematerialization <strong>and</strong> flank<strong>in</strong>g<br />

labour-market measures.<br />

10

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!