05.06.2013 Views

Protectionist Empire: Trade, Tariffs, and United States Foreign Policy ...

Protectionist Empire: Trade, Tariffs, and United States Foreign Policy ...

Protectionist Empire: Trade, Tariffs, and United States Foreign Policy ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Protectionist</strong> <strong>Empire</strong>:<br />

<strong>Trade</strong>, <strong>Tariffs</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, 1890-1914<br />

Abstract<br />

In the 25 years before World War I, the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> involved itself in international politics in<br />

many new ways, acquiring overseas colonies, building a battleship fleet, <strong>and</strong> intervening<br />

increasingly often in Latin America. The widespread belief that foreign markets were necessary<br />

for the country's prosperity contributed to this new foreign policy, but continuing dem<strong>and</strong>s to<br />

protect the home market from foreign competition also influenced it. The politically dominant<br />

Republican Party was strongly committed to trade protection. This commitment led Republican<br />

policy makers to focus on less developed areas of the world that would not export manufactured<br />

goods to the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> rather than on wealthier markets in Europe. It prompted them to seek<br />

exclusive unilateral or bilateral trade concessions with individual trading partners instead of<br />

accepting multilateral arrangements that would have resulted in lower tariffs. Efforts to gain<br />

access to foreign markets while protecting its own also contributed to a more aggressive posture<br />

toward European intervention in the Western Hemisphere. Although the activism of both periods<br />

suggests some superficial similarities, American foreign policy during this period points in a<br />

strikingly different direction than the one taken after 1945.<br />

Benjamin O. Fordham<br />

Department of Political Science<br />

Binghamton University<br />

I am grateful to the John W. Kluge Center at the Library of Congress for providing me with an<br />

ideal place to conduct much of the research for this paper. The National Science Foundation also<br />

supported this project through grant SES-1022546. I am also grateful to my friends <strong>and</strong><br />

colleagues in the Department of Political Science at Binghamton University, who commented on<br />

earlier stages of this work. I am solely responsible for all errors of fact <strong>and</strong> interpretation.


There is no political danger discoverable to Great Britain in American<br />

Imperialism….But to British trade American Imperialism cannot be anything but<br />

a menace. The American <strong>Empire</strong> is a <strong>Protectionist</strong> <strong>Empire</strong>. The "open door" in the<br />

Philippines was never anything but a myth, in which only those who did not know<br />

America could believe (Brooks 1901, 237-8).<br />

The 25 years before World War I are commonly remembered as the era when the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong><br />

became a major power in international politics. The scope of American foreign policy ambition<br />

greatly increased. The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> acquired colonies in the Philippines, Guam, <strong>and</strong> Puerto Rico<br />

in 1898 as a result of the Spanish-American War. American presidents broadened their<br />

interpretation of the Monroe Doctrine's injunction against European intervention in the Americas<br />

while taking diplomatic <strong>and</strong> military actions of their own in the hemisphere increasingly often. In<br />

Asia, they involved themselves in the ongoing controversy among the other major powers over<br />

the future of China. The country's military <strong>and</strong> diplomatic bureaucracy exp<strong>and</strong>ed to<br />

accommodate this new foreign policy activism. The State Department had only 76 employees in<br />

Washington in 1890, a number that grew to 234 by 1910 (Trask 1981, 42). The Army <strong>and</strong> Navy<br />

consisted of roughly 39,000 soldiers <strong>and</strong> sailors in 1890, increasing to nearly 166,000 in 1914<br />

(Carter et al. 2006, Table Ed26-47). The fact that things had changed was obvious to Americans<br />

at the time, prompting much public debate about whether this new departure was wise <strong>and</strong> what<br />

it might mean for the country's future.<br />

What role did the American stake in international trade play in shaping this new foreign<br />

policy? Most answers to this question have focused on the search for export markets. Historians<br />

of the "Wisconsin School," including William Appleman Williams, Walter LaFeber, Thomas<br />

McCormick, <strong>and</strong> others, have argued that there was an elite consensus on the need for foreign<br />

markets. Influential Americans worried about the social <strong>and</strong> political implication of the falling<br />

1


prices <strong>and</strong> the periodic economic crises of the late 19th Century. They became convinced that<br />

rapid economic growth after the Civil War was producing more than the home market could<br />

consume at price levels that provided reasonable profits to producers. Their solution was to find<br />

foreign markets for this "surplus production." The challenges of insuring access to markets in<br />

Asia <strong>and</strong> Latin America explain much of American foreign policy during this period. American<br />

policy makers preferred to rely on diplomatic <strong>and</strong> economic instruments. However, they were<br />

willing to use force when necessary to overcome resistance from economic nationalists in less<br />

developed countries or rival major powers seeking to create exclusive economic <strong>and</strong> political<br />

empires for themselves. Some recent work by political scientists has revisited key features of the<br />

Wisconsin School's argument about the 1890-1914 period, particularly its stress on the political<br />

importance of overseas markets, while adding a new <strong>and</strong> useful emphasis on party <strong>and</strong> regional<br />

competition over foreign policy (e.g., Narizny 2007, 39-158; Trubowitz 1998, 31-95).<br />

Accounts emphasizing the implications of finding export markets provide important<br />

insights into the changes in American foreign policy before World War I, but they tend to<br />

neglect the role of imports. In fact, it is difficult to underst<strong>and</strong> American foreign policy without<br />

considering both these aspects of American participation in international trade. Unlike the search<br />

for export markets, the import side of the story is not one of consensus but of partisan political<br />

conflict. The tariff was a critically important political issue during this period. Alongside the<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for foreign markets, the dominant Republican Party's commitment to protectionism<br />

influenced the policy choices its leaders made. It prompted them to emphasize markets in less<br />

developed areas that would not export manufactured goods to the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. It also led them<br />

to pursue exclusive bilateral arrangements or unilateral privileges in order to gain access to these<br />

markets, especially within the American sphere of influence. They avoided the kinds of<br />

2


multilateral arrangements that would be the cornerstone of <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> policy after World War<br />

II. As the British observer quoted above noted, the American empire of this period was a<br />

protectionist empire. 1 If the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> has also pursued an imperial foreign policy since<br />

1945, it has aimed at a very different kind of empire.<br />

Although the role of trade protection in shaping American foreign policy before World<br />

War I has been relatively neglected since the 1960s, the argument presented here is not entirely<br />

new. Some scholars have examined the connections between protectionism <strong>and</strong> an aggressive<br />

foreign policy in other historical settings (e.g., Carr 1972; Crowley 1966; Milward 1977). Patrick<br />

McDonald's work on trade protection <strong>and</strong> conflict is an especially useful recent contribution<br />

(McDonald 2009). Moreover, as I will explain below, many contemporary observers understood<br />

the foreign policy implications of trade protection before World War I. The goal of this paper is<br />

to set out those implications <strong>and</strong> explain their impact on debates over American foreign policy. It<br />

is part of a larger project that will eventually bring additional evidence to bear on the arguments<br />

presented here.<br />

The remainder of this paper has three parts. The first focuses on the role of trade in<br />

American politics before World War I, including the widely shared beliefs in the importance of<br />

foreign markets <strong>and</strong> the deep partisan divisions over the tariff. The second explains how the<br />

Republican Party's commitment to trade protection complicated the policies needed to gain<br />

access to foreign markets. It also examines how American elites interested in foreign policy<br />

understood the role of trade protection at the time. The third part summarizes the implications of<br />

this evidence for our underst<strong>and</strong>ing of American foreign policy <strong>and</strong> explains how it fits into the<br />

larger project.<br />

1 While Brooks' analysis was published in a British journal, Fortnightly Review, the editors of Literary Digest found<br />

them important enough to be summarized for American readers in their September 14, 1901, issue (American<br />

Imperialism as Viewed Abroad 1901).<br />

3


International <strong>Trade</strong>, Domestic Politics, <strong>and</strong> American <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong><br />

Any account of the role of international trade in American politics in the years before 1914 must<br />

confront two stylized facts, one pertaining to exports, the other to imports. First, there was a<br />

widespread belief among American elites that foreign markets were very important for national<br />

prosperity. Documenting this shared belief is arguably the most important contribution of the<br />

Wisconsin School. Second, the tariff was among the most important <strong>and</strong> divisive political issues<br />

of the day. Republicans favored a protective tariff, especially for manufactured products, while<br />

Democrats tended to prefer lower barriers to imports. This section will review the evidence for<br />

these two premises.<br />

The Search for Export Markets<br />

Historians of the Wisconsin School do not overstate the prevalence of concerns about market<br />

access <strong>and</strong> commercial advantage before 1914. They are pervasive in public discussions of<br />

foreign policy from this period. One typical example of the role these interests played concerns<br />

Whitelaw Reid, a Republican political leader <strong>and</strong> newspaper editor who had helped negotiate the<br />

peace treaty in which Spain ceded the Philippines. Reid gave a series of speeches around the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> to build support for retaining control of the isl<strong>and</strong>s. Naturally, he took pains to<br />

explain that it was legally <strong>and</strong> morally permissible to do so, but he focused on their commercial<br />

value when explaining the benefits of this course of action. He emphasized both their intrinsic<br />

economic potential <strong>and</strong> their usefulness as an "unapproachable foothold" on even more valuable<br />

markets in China. Surprisingly to a present-day reader, Reid had almost nothing to say about<br />

4


their value for American national security. 2 Those who objected to the emerging emphasis on<br />

China in American foreign policy also focused on debunking its prospects as a market for<br />

American goods rather than asserting its irrelevance to American security. 3<br />

Even observers who believed security concerns were more important have noted the<br />

prevalence of economic considerations in commentary about American foreign policy before<br />

World War I. Writing in 1951, George Kennan noted with exasperation the practice of framing<br />

the costs <strong>and</strong> benefits of foreign policy in primarily economic terms. Brooks Adams, whom he<br />

viewed as one of the most prescient writers of the period, had his thinking "distorted by the<br />

materialism of the time" (Kennan 1984, 6). Writers like Adams did not simply downplay security<br />

concerns in favor of economic interests. Instead, they argued that economic concerns defined<br />

security threats <strong>and</strong> interests. International political conflicts were fundamentally quarrels over<br />

economic stakes, especially access to markets. Kennan (1984, 6) thought "fear, ambition,<br />

insecurity, jealousy, <strong>and</strong> perhaps even boredom" were just as important, even though observers<br />

like Adams disagreed. Writers in the Wisconsin School have extensively documented elite<br />

discourse about the role of foreign markets in insuring internal social stability in the face of<br />

"overproduction" <strong>and</strong> falling prices. 4<br />

2<br />

(Whitelaw Reid 1900, 192). He struck similar themes in his commencement address to Miami University of Ohio,<br />

the Princeton University Board of Trustees, <strong>and</strong> the Marquette Club of Chicago, all of which were published<br />

together.<br />

3<br />

For example, John P. Young (1899) argued that the Chinese people lacked both the wealth <strong>and</strong> the desire to<br />

purchase Western manufactured goods. He noted that if they ever did develop a desire for these goods, they would<br />

be able to manufacture them so cheaply that they would undersell the Western producers even in their own home<br />

markets, forcing wage reductions in Western countries.<br />

4 Particularly comprehensive summaries can be found in LaFeber (1963, esp. 150-196); <strong>and</strong> McCormick (1967, esp.<br />

21-52). It is interesting to note the close resemblance between Hobson's (1965 [1902], 71-93) famous account of<br />

"the economic taproot of imperialism" <strong>and</strong> earlier discussions of American foreign policy such as those of Charles<br />

Conant (1899, 1900a, 1900b). Indeed, Conant (1900a, 615) cites one of Hobson's earlier works (Hobson 1894).<br />

While Hobson treated the imperialist search for foreign markets as part of an argument that the British should<br />

renounce it, Conant used nearly the same logic to argue that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> had no choice but to take part in it.<br />

5


In addition to concerns about the domestic economy's need for foreign markets, many<br />

commentators also argued that the economic foundation needed for survival in international<br />

anarchy depended crucially on control of international commerce. They worried that the <strong>United</strong><br />

<strong>States</strong> would be severely disadvantaged if it were denied economic access to the areas that were<br />

then being divided up into European colonial empires. For example, the leading military theorist<br />

of the day, Alfred Thayer Mahan (1987 [1890], 25-8, 83-8), argued that control of maritime trade<br />

had always offered a decisive advantage in world politics, something he hoped would not be<br />

denied to the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. Adams (1900, 40-3) was somewhat more specific, writing about<br />

need for the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>and</strong> Britain to gain commercial control over the Pacific <strong>and</strong> East Asia<br />

in order to compete with the coalition of Eurasian powers he expected to emerge in opposition to<br />

them. Whether based on concern about domestic political <strong>and</strong> social stability or international<br />

competitiveness, the bottom line was that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> needed access to foreign markets.<br />

Particularly under the circumstances of the late 19th Century, access to foreign markets<br />

was not simply a private concern for traders <strong>and</strong> investors. It also had major foreign policy<br />

implications. Accounts of state efforts to promote or regulate international trade usually focus on<br />

policies aimed directly at private economic actors such as tariffs, subsidies, exchange controls,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the like. To some extent, it makes sense to treat these policies separately from political-<br />

military issues on which the stakes are potentially broader. Nevertheless, maintaining the<br />

essential conditions for international trade has important implications for matters not usually<br />

considered part of "foreign economic policy." Although international trade is usually carried on<br />

by firms, the conditions that make it possible involve more than just interested buyers <strong>and</strong><br />

sellers. Threats to trade can come from within one of the trading partners, either through the<br />

actions of local authorities or because of internal conflict that is beyond their control. The<br />

6


political or military actions of third states might also endanger commerce. Even state leaders<br />

interested not in political control but only market access for their citizens might end up<br />

intervening politically or militarily when confronting these circumstances, a process John<br />

Gallagher <strong>and</strong> Ronald Robinson called "the imperialism of free trade" in the context of mid-<br />

Victorian British foreign policy (Gallagher <strong>and</strong> Robinson 1953). Scholars who emphasize the<br />

economic sources of American foreign policy have frequently applied this idea to the <strong>United</strong><br />

<strong>States</strong>, noting that American leaders' interest in increasing the country's exports led them to adopt<br />

a policy of political <strong>and</strong> military intervention overseas even though they had only a limited<br />

interest in acquiring colonies. 5<br />

American policy makers interested in exp<strong>and</strong>ing access to overseas markets during the<br />

years before World War I confronted a variety of threats that could only be overcome through<br />

diplomacy or military action by the state. <strong>Tariffs</strong> on American exports had long been high in<br />

Latin America, <strong>and</strong> rose steadily in Europe after the 1870s (Coatsworth <strong>and</strong> Williamson 2004;<br />

Findlay <strong>and</strong> O'Rourke 2007, 395-6). Internal political conflicts such as the Boxer Rebellion in<br />

China disrupted trade <strong>and</strong> sometimes prompted American military intervention. These<br />

interventions were far more frequent in the Caribbean Basin where American policy makers<br />

acted not only to protect American economic interests but also to preclude similar actions by<br />

European powers. The empire-building efforts of these powers also threatened American trade in<br />

some parts of the world. The recent division of nearly the entire African continent into European<br />

colonies was an ominous precedent for Americans worried about being denied economic access<br />

to these empires. Preventing a comparable colonization process in Latin America was a<br />

5 Explicit references to Gallagher <strong>and</strong> Robinson's concept are widespread. See, for example, McCormick 1967, 63;<br />

Topik 1996, 4; <strong>and</strong> W. A. Williams 2009, 96. "The imperialism of free trade" was a provocative phrase in 1953<br />

because imperialism was then generally associated with protectionism. That the phrase no longer appears ironic<br />

reveals something important about how our underst<strong>and</strong>ing of "imperialism" has changed.<br />

7


longst<strong>and</strong>ing priority enshrined in the Monroe Doctrine <strong>and</strong> enforced more aggressively after<br />

1895. Following the acquisition of the Philippines, American policy makers also sought to<br />

prevent the partition of China, most notably through the Open Door notes of 1899-1900, an<br />

attempt to get all the major powers to agree to allow equal economic access to the country.<br />

The Political Importance of the Tariff<br />

Dem<strong>and</strong>s for foreign markets were not the only way that international trade entered American<br />

politics. The highly partisan conflict over the protective tariff was another. Unlike concerns<br />

about access to overseas markets, there was emphatically not a consensus on trade protection<br />

during the late 19th <strong>and</strong> early 20th centuries. The tariff was among the most important<br />

differences between the two parties during this period. The Republican Party was strongly<br />

committed to trade protection, especially after 1887 (Goldstein 1993, 19-20; Bailey, Goldstein,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Weingast 1997, 611; Bensel 2000, 457-509; Irwin <strong>and</strong> Kroszner 1999; Epstein <strong>and</strong><br />

O'Halloran 1996; Taussig 1910, 216-9). This was as apparent to political actors at the time as it<br />

has been to subsequent scholars. Republican presidents could not easily ab<strong>and</strong>on or even<br />

moderate this commitment. As Bensel (2000, 457-509) explains in some detail, tariffs provided a<br />

vital incentive for key constituencies to support other aspects of the Republican Party's program.<br />

More than 99 percent of Republicans in Congress voted for trade protection between 1888 <strong>and</strong><br />

1897. Less than 4 percent of Democrats took this position (Bensel 2000, 471). Both McKinley<br />

<strong>and</strong> Roosevelt sought to extend tariff reductions to some European states in exchange for<br />

corresponding concessions on American exports. These efforts resulted only on attacks on their<br />

leadership from within their own party <strong>and</strong> were quickly ab<strong>and</strong>oned. 6<br />

6 On McKinley's unsuccessful reciprocity treaties, see (Laughlin <strong>and</strong> Willis 1903, 367-401) <strong>and</strong> Schoenhof (1902).<br />

Republican criticism of Theodore Roosevelt's comments on the need to negotiate more reciprocity treaties is<br />

8


Dem<strong>and</strong>s for protection came mainly from manufacturers, though producers of wool <strong>and</strong><br />

sugar also played a role. By contrast, many American agricultural commodities were highly<br />

competitive <strong>and</strong> provided the lion's share of American exports before World War I. As Figure 1<br />

indicates, cotton was by far the largest American export through the entire period, comprising<br />

roughly one quarter of all exports from the end of Reconstruction through 1914. Tobacco <strong>and</strong><br />

wheat were also quite important. Exports of iron <strong>and</strong> steel, machinery, <strong>and</strong> automobiles--a much<br />

broader category than the other two depicted in Figure 1--were still relatively unimportant at the<br />

time the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> began its career as a colonial power in 1898. Though manufactured<br />

exports increased steadily, they remained less important than agriculture through 1914. Under<br />

these circumstances, the tariff transferred wealth from farmers to manufacturers. As one scholar<br />

wrote in the North American Review, "[o]ur farmer sells on the basis of Liverpool prices in the<br />

market of the world. He buys home productions at a protected price, <strong>and</strong> thus he is hit both<br />

ways" (Selbie 1893, 254). As readers of the Literary Digest were periodically informed, foreign<br />

observers noted the same redistributive feature of the tariff in the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> (e.g., America<br />

<strong>and</strong> Protection 1890; The McKinley Bill 1890; Protectionism in the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> 1891; The<br />

Ruin of the American Farmer 1892; The American Tariff--Past <strong>and</strong> Future 1892).<br />

[Figure 1 about here.]<br />

Because manufacturing was concentrated in the Northeast, this transfer of wealth had a<br />

regional as well as sectoral dimension. Figure 2 depicts the extent of this regional concentration<br />

in 1900. Aside from Montana <strong>and</strong> Arizona, small populations <strong>and</strong> large mineral smelting<br />

industries created a surprisingly large figure for value-added per capita, income from<br />

manufacturing was heavily concentrated in the Northeast. The 15 states between New Engl<strong>and</strong><br />

reported in the Literary Digest (Republican Opposition to President Roosevelt 1905). Roosevelt subsequently sought<br />

no such treaties.<br />

9


<strong>and</strong> the Great Lakes accounted for 77 percent of employment <strong>and</strong> output in manufacturing, <strong>and</strong><br />

79 percent of capital invested in the sector in 1900 (<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> Census Bureau 1901). 7 By<br />

increasing income from manufacturing at the expense of other economic activities, trade<br />

protection redistributed income from the rest of the country to the Northeast. The fact that the<br />

revenue from the tariff helped fund pensions for Union veterans of the Civil War further<br />

reinforced its regional redistributive effects.<br />

[Figure 2 about here.]<br />

Advocates of trade protection maintained that manufacturing was simply more important<br />

than agriculture for the future of the country. The Literary Digest summarized a debate over the<br />

international trade between a Republican <strong>and</strong> a Democrat from The Californian in the run up to<br />

the 1892 election. The Republican, Richard McDonald, argued that the tariff would eventually<br />

end what he saw as overreliance on agricultural exports as well as insuring that Americans did<br />

not import manufactured goods they could make for themselves. Arguing that "[t]he best trade is<br />

between nations whose productions are different," he hoped that trade with Europe would<br />

decline (Our Commercial Growth <strong>and</strong> the Tariff: A Republican View 1892). These views about<br />

agriculture were repeated frequently both inside <strong>and</strong> outside the government. Worthington C.<br />

Ford, a specialist on trade with the State <strong>and</strong> Treasury Departments, welcomed the growing share<br />

of manufactures among American exports, noting that agricultural commodities were subject to<br />

dangerous price fluctuations (Ford 1898). The manufacturer Charles R. Flint offered a series of<br />

reasons for focusing on finding foreign markets for manufactured exports rather than agricultural<br />

raw materials, including their higher profit margins <strong>and</strong> increasing importance in the American<br />

7 The states included in this category are Connecticut, Illinois, Indiana, Massachusetts, Maine, Michigan, Minnesota,<br />

New Hampshire, New Jersey, New York, Ohio, Pennsylvania, Rhode Isl<strong>and</strong>, Vermont, <strong>and</strong> Wisconsin.<br />

10


economy. He saw Latin American markets as especially promising, provided they could be<br />

weaned away from their preference for European products (Flint 1897).<br />

Not surprisingly, these arguments did not convince the political representatives of most<br />

agricultural areas of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. Senator George Vest of Missouri summarized their<br />

position in North American Review prior to the 1892 election.<br />

The existing tariff is an obstruction to healthy <strong>and</strong> legitimate commerce. It<br />

narrows <strong>and</strong> restricts the markets for American products, <strong>and</strong> especially those of<br />

agriculture. It is based upon the idea that the American farmer must look to the<br />

home market alone, <strong>and</strong> if that does not give remunerative prices for his surplus,<br />

the loss must be borne patiently <strong>and</strong> patriotically for the general welfare (Vest<br />

1892, 402-3).<br />

Other members of Congress representing similar interests made much the same point during<br />

elections <strong>and</strong> tariff debates (e.g., Mills 1890; Herbert 1892; Wilson 1892). They hoped to reduce<br />

reliance on the tariff for revenue <strong>and</strong> replace it with an income tax that they hoped would fall<br />

more heavily on manufacturers. As Roger Mills (1894, 237) put it in defending this element of<br />

the 1894 tariff bill, "[w]e produce over eight billions of manufactured products protected against<br />

competition: it would not be unjust to call on it for a contribution." As congressional voting on<br />

the issue suggests, these views were common among those representing agricultural areas<br />

(Bensel 2000, 471).<br />

Although tariff reformers had a few successes along the way, advocates of trade<br />

protection retained the upper h<strong>and</strong> politically during this period. The nation's population, like its<br />

manufacturing industries, was concentrated in the Northeast. The 15 manufacturing states in the<br />

Northeast <strong>and</strong> Great Lakes region held 214 of the 224 electoral votes needed to win the<br />

presidency in the 1900 election <strong>and</strong> was similarly critical in all the other elections during the<br />

11


1890-1914 period. 8 Democratic c<strong>and</strong>idates, who typically endorsed "tariff reform," needed to<br />

win at least a few of these manufacturing states in order to gain the White House. They<br />

accomplished this difficult task only twice in the seven elections between 1888 <strong>and</strong> 1912. By<br />

contrast, advocates of trade protection could assemble a successful electoral coalition by gaining<br />

only a few agricultural states, something they sought to do by protecting domestic producers of<br />

wool <strong>and</strong> sugar in addition to manufactures. Their need for Northeastern support gave<br />

Democratic presidents a good reason to avoid an extreme position on rolling back the tariff,<br />

however much many prominent Democratic members of Congress wanted to do so. While the<br />

tariff bill that Woodrow Wilson signed in 1913 indeed provided substantial reductions, the 1894<br />

tariff bill signed by Grover Clevel<strong>and</strong> did not. 9 Overall, the political case for trade protection<br />

was compelling, especially to Republicans, who controlled the presidency for most of the 1890-<br />

1914 period.<br />

The <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> Implications of Protectionism<br />

The tendency of most scholars to focus on dem<strong>and</strong>s for access to potential export markets tends<br />

to highlight the similarities between American "Open Door imperialism" after 1890 <strong>and</strong> the<br />

British "imperialism of free trade." Yet American imperialism during this period was not<br />

associated with free trade. Its most vociferous advocates came from the party most strongly<br />

committed to protecting the domestic market. Republicans occupied the White House for 19 of<br />

the 25 years between 1890 <strong>and</strong> 1914, <strong>and</strong> held both houses of Congress for nearly that long. No<br />

8 These states also had 214 electoral votes in the 1892 <strong>and</strong> 1896 elections, when the total needed for victory was 223<br />

<strong>and</strong> 224, respectively. The comparable numbers for the other elections were 229 of 239 votes needed in 1904, 229 of<br />

242 in 1908, <strong>and</strong> 249 of 266 in 1912 (U.S. National Archives <strong>and</strong> Records Administration 2011).<br />

9 The author of the bill acknowledged at the time that the Wilson Tariff did not go as far as he would have liked in<br />

reducing trade protection, but he defended it as a reasonable beginning (Wilson 1894).<br />

12


Democratic president won reelection between the Civil War <strong>and</strong> World War I, so their ability to<br />

reshape American foreign policy was limited. Predictably, American protectionists denied that<br />

their preferred commercial policy posed any problems for American foreign policy. The political<br />

predominance of this faction <strong>and</strong> its rhetoric may have helped obscure the difficulties of building<br />

a protectionist empire. A closer examination of the foreign policy debates of the time suggests<br />

that these difficulties were quite real <strong>and</strong> that they became increasingly clear to both American<br />

<strong>and</strong> foreign observers over time. This section will review the policy debates of the 1890-1914<br />

period in order to suggest that key aspects of American foreign policy make sense only once one<br />

considers the implications of trade protection.<br />

I will focus on the public debate in periodicals that reached an elite audience rather than<br />

on the deliberations within the state for two reasons. First, the foreign policy bureaucracy was<br />

extremely small by current st<strong>and</strong>ards. The State Department's Washington staff in 1950 was<br />

more than 36 times its then seemingly enormous size in 1910. The military establishment also<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed during <strong>and</strong> after World War II to a size that would have amazed the policy makers of<br />

1900. There is no 1900 counterpart to NSC 68 because the capacity to produce such a<br />

comprehensive policy statement simply did not exist inside the American state at the time.<br />

Second, there was far less official secrecy before World War I. In 1914, reporters were still able<br />

to w<strong>and</strong>er freely through the State Department's offices, reading more or less whatever they<br />

chose (West 1978, 78). Even if they kept their correspondence away from prying journalists,<br />

policy makers could not feel confident that it would be kept secret. The <strong>Foreign</strong> Relations of the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> series, a st<strong>and</strong>ard reference for American diplomatic historians, began in 1861 as a<br />

set of documents furnished to Congress each December as part of the president's annual message<br />

<strong>and</strong> promptly published. The published documents dated from the current calendar year until<br />

13


1906, when the dem<strong>and</strong>s of assembling an increasingly large set of records delayed its<br />

publication by three years. The documents often revealed sources of intelligence <strong>and</strong> sensitive<br />

policy deliberations that would now routinely be classified. The attenuation of secret policy<br />

making processes within the state greatly increased the relative importance of the public debates<br />

conducted in periodicals like the North American Review, Atlantic, <strong>and</strong> Forum, that circulated<br />

among influential Americans. 10 Indeed, high-ranking military officers <strong>and</strong> State Department<br />

officials often published articles setting out their own positions in these journals.<br />

Republican presidents' need to respond to dem<strong>and</strong>s for both increased access to foreign<br />

markets <strong>and</strong> continuing trade protection, especially against manufactured imports, influenced<br />

their foreign policy choices in at least three ways. First, it led them to focus on markets in less<br />

developed areas even though these were poorer <strong>and</strong> less promising than those in wealthier parts<br />

of the world. Second, it limited the means through which they could promote American exports,<br />

leading them to seek special bilateral arrangements or unilateral trade concessions rather than<br />

multilateral processes like those American policy makers would pursue after 1945. Third,<br />

protectionism gave American foreign policy an aggressive <strong>and</strong> unilateralist tone that limited<br />

prospects for participating in broader schemes for international cooperation.<br />

The Emphasis on Less Developed Markets<br />

One of the most obvious difficulties with the claim that concern about export markets was at the<br />

heart of American foreign policy during the 1890-1914 period is that policy makers focused on<br />

relatively poor markets, slighting the wealthier parts of the world that actually imported more<br />

American products. As Figure 3 indicates, Europe had long been the recipient of roughly 80<br />

10 Identifying politically significant journals poses problems of its own. The approach adopted here is to focus on<br />

those covered in Literary Digest, a magazine whose self-conscious purpose during this period was to summarize<br />

contemporary thought on a range of current issues for an educated audience (Peterson 1964, 154).<br />

14


percent of U.S. exports at the time the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> began acquiring overseas colonies in 1898.<br />

Latin America <strong>and</strong> Asia gradually increased their shares during the remaining decade <strong>and</strong> a half<br />

before World War I, but Europe remained the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>' best export market. Nevertheless, as<br />

LaFeber (1963), McCormick (1967), <strong>and</strong> others have documented, Americans concerned about<br />

overseas markets wrote mostly about Latin America <strong>and</strong> East Asia. The puzzle deepens when<br />

one considers that access to longst<strong>and</strong>ing European markets before 1914 entailed many fewer of<br />

the dangerous <strong>and</strong> costly foreign policy problems that plagued market access in less developed<br />

areas. It required neither battleships nor colonies. These regional priorities make more sense<br />

when one considers the implications of trade protection in the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. Maintaining high<br />

tariff barriers, especially on manufactured goods, complicated policy makers' efforts to promote<br />

American exports. These complications were easier to h<strong>and</strong>le when dealing with less-developed<br />

trading partners.<br />

[Figure 3 about here.]<br />

Advocates of free trade always argued that protectionism would interfere with American<br />

exports. Representative Roger Mills of Texas, one of the principal Democratic advocates of tariff<br />

reduction, made this point repeatedly during the debate on the protectionist McKinley Tariff of<br />

1890. "When protection puts taxes on the goods of the foreigner that prohibit them from coming<br />

here, he is rendered less able to take in exchange the surplus which we are ready <strong>and</strong> anxious to<br />

give" (Mills 1890, 163). 11 Like other protectionists, McKinley denied that there was any<br />

connection between exports <strong>and</strong> the tariff. "[<strong>Tariffs</strong>] put no restraint upon foreign trade"<br />

(McKinley 1890, 747). As Terrill (1973) has pointed out, the protectionists were correct, at least<br />

11 Many others made much the same point during other tariff debates. For example, Procter (1893) predicted the<br />

more liberal tariff under consideration in 1893 would permit the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> to surpass Britain as the leading<br />

commercial power. A. A. Healy (1893, 407-8) took the same view, noting that "foreign nations need more of our<br />

products <strong>and</strong> would be glad to buy them, but they cannot buy if we will not allow the products they have to send us<br />

in payment to our ports." See also Medley 1893.<br />

15


in a narrow sense. In a multilateral trading system, bilateral exports <strong>and</strong> imports do not have to<br />

balance. Moreover, flows of European investment into the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> also helped reduce<br />

potential balance-of-payments problems during this period. Nevertheless, as the size of the<br />

American economy <strong>and</strong> the volume of American trade steadily increased during the late 19th<br />

century, continuing American trade protection posed increasing difficulties for the international<br />

trading system.<br />

The prospect of European tariff retaliation posed a more immediate threat to American<br />

exports than long-term difficulties with the balance of payments. Protected American products<br />

were frequently sold overseas for less than their price in the protected home market. "Dumping,"<br />

the term used to describe this practice then <strong>and</strong> now, was a common result of tariff protection. Its<br />

purpose, after all was to raise domestic prices above prevailing on the world market. Dumping<br />

outraged foreign competitors as well as American proponents of free trade. 12 The Belgian<br />

economist Gustave de Molinari summed up the European reaction to the 1890 McKinley tariff<br />

for an American audience in the North American Review, pointing out that the bill strengthened<br />

the h<strong>and</strong> of protectionists there <strong>and</strong> had even led to talk of a customs union directed against the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> (de Molinari 1890). The Literary Digest summarized Molinari's comments for its<br />

readers (The McKinley Bill in Europe 1890) <strong>and</strong> reported other European views of the McKinley<br />

Tariff, which were uniformly negative <strong>and</strong> proposed various plans for retaliation (e.g., The<br />

American Tariff War 1890; French Comment on the Tariff Bill 1890; America <strong>and</strong> Protection<br />

1890; The McKinley Bill 1890). Subsequent protectionist tariff bills elicited a similar European<br />

response that was duly reported in the American press. For example, the economist <strong>and</strong> diplomat<br />

Jacob Schoenhof (1898, 550) warned readers of The Forum that "the new [Dingley] tariff<br />

12 Litman (1909, 314-5) <strong>and</strong> Clark (1907) provide contemporary discussions of American dumping.<br />

16


exercises the severest pressures against those countries which have become our best customers in<br />

manufactured goods." Retaliation was a likely result. James Howard Gore (1899) offered a more<br />

specific account of the German efforts to reduce its food imports from the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> in<br />

response to the burden the Dingley Tariff imposed on its manufactured exports.<br />

The prospect of European retaliation did not deter American protectionists. Because<br />

Britain was both the largest European importer of American products <strong>and</strong> the only country not to<br />

retaliate in kind against American tariffs, plans for an imperial preference system that would<br />

discriminate against American imports were especially ominous. The Literary Digest found that<br />

newspaper editorialists generally expected the scheme to harm the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> if it were<br />

implemented. Some protectionist papers apparently redoubled their support for the tariff,<br />

however. As one such editor put it "[a]ll this country needs to do is to keep on the way it has<br />

been going. Build up its industries by protection, seek markets in South America, China, <strong>and</strong><br />

other such countries, <strong>and</strong> nothing that European nations can do in the way of tariff barriers will<br />

check or stop our growth" (America <strong>and</strong> Joseph Chamberlain 1903, 494).<br />

As this quotation suggests, protectionists interested in foreign markets saw a brighter<br />

future in Latin America <strong>and</strong> Asia than in Europe, even though the value of exports to these areas<br />

remained relatively small. There was little local competition for American manufactures in these<br />

parts of the world, so the concerns about dumping <strong>and</strong> the inequities of American tariffs did not<br />

arise. Whitelaw Reid (1900, 41-2) summarized this line of argument as part of his case for<br />

annexing the Philippines.<br />

That way lies now the best hope of American commerce. There you may<br />

comm<strong>and</strong> a natural rather than an artificial trade--a trade which pushes itself<br />

instead of needing to be pushed; a trade with people who can send you things you<br />

want <strong>and</strong> cannot produce, <strong>and</strong> take from you in return things they want <strong>and</strong> cannot<br />

produce; in other words, a trade largely between different zones, <strong>and</strong> largely with<br />

less advanced peoples, comprising one fourth the population of the globe, whose<br />

17


wants promise to be speedily <strong>and</strong> enormously developed. The Atlantic Ocean<br />

carries mainly a different trade, with people as advanced as ourselves, who could<br />

produce or procure elsewhere much of what they buy from us, while we could<br />

produce, if driven to it, most of what we buy from them. It is more or less,<br />

therefore, an artificial trade as well as a trade in which we have lost the first place<br />

<strong>and</strong> will find it difficult to regain.<br />

The idea that trade with less developed areas would not create pressure to reduce<br />

domestic tariffs on manufactured products prompted James Blaine, Secretary of State during the<br />

Harrison administration, to include a measure to promote trade with Latin America in the<br />

McKinley tariff bill in 1890. Not coincidentally, Blaine was among the most prominent<br />

Republican advocates of protectionism (e.g., Gladstone <strong>and</strong> Blaine 1890). His plan for<br />

reciprocity agreements with Latin American states followed in the wake of the Pan-American<br />

conference over which he had presided a few months earlier, a meeting that was also directed at<br />

increasing <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> trade with its southern neighbors (Hannigan 2002, 54-6). The<br />

reciprocity measure in the McKinley Tariff used the threat of punitive duties on sugar <strong>and</strong> a few<br />

other products to secure reciprocity agreements permitting American access to markets in<br />

countries that would have little cause to complain about high American tariffs on manufactured<br />

products (Laughlin <strong>and</strong> Willis 1903, 185-6; D. Healy 1970, 162-4). Opponents of the McKinley<br />

Tariff argued that focusing on less-developed trading partners who would export agricultural<br />

products to the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> would further disadvantage American agriculture, already harmed<br />

by higher prices for protected manufactured goods (e.g., Herbert 1892; Mills 1891; Vest 1892).<br />

The political forces backing the tariff kept Republican presidents focused on less-<br />

developed markets even when they would have preferred a broader approach. Europe remained a<br />

richer market than either Latin America or East Asia, even for many manufacturers. For this<br />

reason, some Republicans hoped to use reciprocity agreements to lower European tariff barriers<br />

as well. Democrats had managed to repeal the reciprocity provisions of the McKinley tariff in<br />

18


1894, but the Dingley Tariff, adopted after sweeping Republican electoral victories of 1896,<br />

revived them. The McKinley administration then negotiated reciprocity treaties with European as<br />

well as Latin American states. The treaty with France was especially controversial, prompting<br />

the National Association of Manufacturers to call a special "National Reciprocity Convention" so<br />

that its members could debate the treaties publicly. Some of those present, most notably<br />

representative of agricultural implements manufacturers, spoke out in favor of offering tariff<br />

concessions to the French in exchange for lower tariffs on some American exports. Others were<br />

strongly opposed, however. Some pointed out that the reciprocity plank of the 1900 Republican<br />

Party platform had called only for trade with states that would export nothing produced in the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>, a condition that might hold in Latin America but certainly not in Europe.<br />

Particularly canny opponents of the treaties also pointed out that the practice of allowing some<br />

manufacturers to be harmed so that others could benefit set a dangerous precedent. It would be<br />

better if the "forces of protection" that the convention embodied remained united. "The country<br />

is looking at you. If you make a blunder, <strong>and</strong> allow individual interests to lead you too far, you<br />

may lead us between the conflicting forces of fair trade <strong>and</strong> free trade, <strong>and</strong> we may be shot to<br />

pieces." In the end, convention endorsed reciprocity "only where it can be done without injury to<br />

any of our home interests of manufacturing, commerce or farming." 13 The convention's verdict<br />

carried substantial political weight. President Roosevelt tempered his support for the treaties,<br />

which had been negotiated under his predecessor, <strong>and</strong> the Senate refused to ratify any of them<br />

(Hoxie 1903, 208-9). Writing after the convention in Forum, editorialist E. J. Gibson (1901, 477)<br />

13 National Association of Manufacturers 1901. For the position of agricultural implement manufacturers, see pages<br />

14-20. Comments on the Republican Party platform can be found on pages 21 <strong>and</strong> 43, among others. Concerns about<br />

the precedent set by concessions affecting some members of the protectionist coalition can be found on page 64. The<br />

final resolution on reciprocity can be found on page 145. The Literary Digest documented the extensive press<br />

coverage <strong>and</strong> editorial commentary on the convention (Net Results of the Reciprocity Convention 1901). (Laughlin<br />

<strong>and</strong> Willis 1903, 346-8) also emphasize the importance of appeals for solidarity among protectionists at the<br />

convention as a major reason for the failure of the McKinley administration's treaties.<br />

19


summarized the reasons for the outcome. "When we go outside the lines laid down in the last<br />

Republican National platform favoring treaties that 'open our markets on favorable terms for<br />

what we do not ourselves produce,' it is very difficult to make a reciprocity treaty not in conflict<br />

with the protective tariff."<br />

Some policy makers recognized the political constraints that protectionism imposed even<br />

before the failure of the McKinley administration's reciprocity treaties. Many would certainly<br />

have preferred free trade or at least a more moderate approach than the politics of the Republican<br />

Party would permit, but their personal opinions did not alter the political reality they faced. 14<br />

Addressing a convention on international trade in 1899, James C. Monaghan, then a U.S. consul<br />

in Germany <strong>and</strong> later head of the division of consular reports, noted with some frustration both<br />

foreign complaints about the tariff <strong>and</strong> the defiant attitude of American protectionists. "The fact<br />

that almost if not quite every foreign country or foreign delegate has entered a protest against the<br />

tariff conditions existing in this country will be to the larger part of this people a splendid<br />

argument in favor of the continuation of the tariff." Monaghan's assigned topic was trade with<br />

Northern Europe. He noted that Europe was indeed a richer market but he also pointed out that<br />

"just as long as any manufactured article or product of the machines of this country begins to be<br />

imported in any large quantities into the countries of Europe, the statesmen of those countries<br />

will enact protective <strong>and</strong> sometimes prohibitory duties on those articles." He concluded that "it<br />

may be wiser <strong>and</strong> better to pay even more attention to the East <strong>and</strong> to Russia than to Europe, but<br />

I certainly say this, let us neglect neither" (Butler 1899, 289-91).<br />

14 For example, Ulysses Eddy, whom McCormick (1967, 42) cites as advocate of reciprocity treaties in the 1890s,<br />

also wrote a satire attacking the tariff <strong>and</strong> other government policies that interfered with trade (Eddy 1892). Many<br />

other Republicans were at least privately willing to consider lower tariffs (Wolman 1992).<br />

20


The Need for Exclusive Bilateral Arrangements <strong>and</strong> Unilateral Privileges<br />

The reciprocity agreements that Republican administrations sought to negotiate under the<br />

McKinley <strong>and</strong> Dingley <strong>Tariffs</strong> were not steps toward broader free trade. They were intended to<br />

be limited exceptions embedded within a strongly protectionist commercial policy framework.<br />

They were negotiated on a few goods--ideally those not produced in the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>--<strong>and</strong> were<br />

strictly bilateral. Until 1923, the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> did not recognize unconditional most-favored<br />

nation (MFN) status in international trade. After 1945, unconditional MFN would form the basis<br />

for the multilateral trading system. Through it, bilateral tariff concessions negotiated under the<br />

rules of the General Agreement on <strong>Tariffs</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> the World <strong>Trade</strong> Organization are<br />

generalized to the other parties to these agreements. Under the pre-1923 "American<br />

interpretation" of MFN, trade concessions granted to another state in exchange for some special<br />

consideration were not automatically extended to other states just because they enjoyed MFN<br />

status. Instead, the benefits of MFN status applied only to concessions granted to other another<br />

state without receiving a reciprocal favor in return. 15 Because nearly all other states had accepted<br />

the unconditional interpretation of MFN status by the 1890s, the anomalous American position<br />

caused frequent disputes with its trading partners. The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> did grant unconditional<br />

MFN status in a few unusual instances, but it generally avoided this step even when it was costly<br />

to do so. In 1898, the Swiss minister in Washington managed to convince the State Department<br />

that his country's 1850 trade agreement with the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> entitled Switzerl<strong>and</strong> to the same<br />

duties accorded the French under a newly negotiated reciprocity agreement. To stave off similar<br />

claims from other states, the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> abrogated the commercial treaty with Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

after the required one-year notification period (C. L. Jones 1908, 123-4).<br />

15 Useful discussion of conditional <strong>and</strong> unconditional MFN status include (C. L. Jones 1908; Viner 1924).<br />

21


The conditional interpretation of MFN <strong>and</strong> provisions for bilateral reciprocity agreements<br />

made discrimination against some trading partners <strong>and</strong> in favor of others a matter of policy--one<br />

that rests uneasily with historical accounts that emphasize the Open Door Notes as the basis for<br />

American policy in general. After 1899, the American diplomats indeed promoted the principle<br />

that traders from all nations should have equal access to markets in all parts of China, regardless<br />

of any special political influence particular powers enjoyed there. This policy must be viewed in<br />

light of the fact that the other powers had already carved out spheres of influence in China by<br />

1899, when American bases in the Philippines made the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> a player in the politics of<br />

the region. A partition of China among these powers appeared likely. 16 The Open Door Notes<br />

were an effort to secure the greatest possible economic access for the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> in one<br />

particular country, not a general principle. The policy of non-discrimination in China did not<br />

slow American efforts to set up exclusive bilateral arrangements in Latin America. Moreover,<br />

Sidney Brooks' prediction, quoted at the beginning of this paper, that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> would not<br />

adhere to the open-door policy in the Philippines turned out to be correct. 17 The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong><br />

kept its promise that it would not discriminate in favor its exports to the Philippines for ten years<br />

after annexing the isl<strong>and</strong>s in 1899. However, this practice ended promptly in 1909, when new<br />

legislation eliminated duties on trade between the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Philippines while<br />

16 For example, addressing the American Academy for the Advancement of Political <strong>and</strong> Social Science on U.S.<br />

policy toward China, both Ford (1899) <strong>and</strong> Hill (1899) assumed that partition was inevitable. Some in the audience<br />

disputed this premise, but mainly to argue that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> needed to act more aggressively to prevent it. The<br />

Boxer Rebellion increased speculation about partition <strong>and</strong> debate about whether the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> could (or should)<br />

prevent it (Shall America Join in the Partition of China? 1900).<br />

17 Brooks was not alone in his skepticism of American commitment to an open-door policy. Other British observers,<br />

as well as British <strong>and</strong> French editorialists, all questioned it, noting especially American protective tariffs at home<br />

(The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Open Door 1900; The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> as a World Power 1899). The Literary Digest<br />

provided ground for skepticism about the permanence of the open door policy in the Philippines, quoting Rep.<br />

Nelson Dingley (R-ME), chairman of the House Ways <strong>and</strong> Means Committee: "It is to be borne in mind, however,<br />

that the present talk about an 'open door' policy for the Philippines is intended to apply entirely to these isl<strong>and</strong>s while<br />

under a military administration, which would be permissible, <strong>and</strong> not to apply to those isl<strong>and</strong>s after they shall have<br />

been formally recognized as part of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>" (The Open Door 1898, 680).<br />

22


imposing a tariff on other states' exports to the isl<strong>and</strong>s (Culbertson 1919, 333-4). Some advocates<br />

of tariff reform indeed argued that the principle of equal treatment implied in the Open Door<br />

Notes should indeed be universal (Wolman 1992). Their position had little policy impact before<br />

World War I.<br />

The commitment to both trade protection <strong>and</strong> finding foreign markets would have made<br />

acceptance of unconditional MFN difficult even if American leaders had been inclined to do so.<br />

The system of strictly bilateral reciprocity allowed them to select the most promising potential<br />

markets without making politically sensitive changes in the overall tariff rate. Extending the<br />

same concessions they made under these agreements to all states that could claim MFN status<br />

would have been equivalent to reducing the tariff overall. The prospect that other states might<br />

extend the concessions they granted to the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> to their other trading partners was less<br />

threatening, but would diminish the competitive advantage a special tariff rate gave American<br />

exporters. Perhaps because they were accustomed to seeking these advantages through the tariff<br />

anyway, politically active business leaders were not afraid to suggest that the government should<br />

seek out exclusive privileges when negotiating reciprocity agreements. As Henry Dalley of the<br />

New York Board of <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Transportation put it during the 1901 National Reciprocity<br />

Convention, "[w]e can certainly justify it to ourselves if we (following the examples of other<br />

nations) secure such advantages as we are entitled to through our comm<strong>and</strong>ing position in the<br />

world of commerce" (National Association of Manufacturers 1901, 41). Others were more<br />

specific about the advantages they had in mind. William Bass of the South Brooklyn Board of<br />

<strong>Trade</strong> argued that a workable reciprocity arrangement had to "exclude European productions<br />

from our Latin neighbors" (National Association of Manufacturers 1901, 37). Such exclusive<br />

privileges were not easy to obtain from Latin American states because they served only to<br />

23


provide a rent to the American exporter. As Taussig (1910, 240) pointed out, "[c]oncessions of<br />

this sort, however, which do redound to the ultimate advantage of the communities giving them,<br />

are not likely long to remain preferential."<br />

Reciprocity agreements were not the only means through which American policy makers<br />

sought to secure privileged market access for American exports. In any event, these agreements<br />

did not prove particularly successful. Those negotiated under the 1890 McKinley Tariff were<br />

repealed in 1894, when the Democrats gained control of Congress. The resurgent Republicans<br />

reintroduced the idea in the 1897 Dingley Tariff but the Senate refused to ratify the treaties the<br />

McKinley administration negotiated. American policy makers turned instead to other means of<br />

obtaining privileged market access. The Supreme Court upheld the constitutionality of setting<br />

separate tariffs for American overseas possessions in 1901 (Wolman 1992, 15). The <strong>United</strong><br />

<strong>States</strong> could thus impose its preferred trade policy on U.S. colonies, an alternative to reciprocity<br />

treaties that some observers thought undermined support for these treaties at a time when further<br />

colonial expansion was possible. In the case of the Philippines, the military occupation<br />

authorities solicited suggestions from American business when setting tariff rates, finding ways<br />

of favoring American products even before the formal repeal of the open door policy there was<br />

permissible. Meanwhile, Philippine products exported to the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> paid the full rates set<br />

out in the Dingley Tariff until the tariff was revised in 1909 (Hoxie 1903, 210-13; <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong><br />

Senate 1902). Cuba was not formally a colony but remained effectively an American<br />

protectorate. It had to accept a reciprocity agreement that fell far short of the free trade Cuban<br />

political leaders had wanted (Speck 2005).<br />

The 1909 Payne-Aldrich Tariff moved away from reciprocity treaties, adopting an<br />

alternative approach copied from French practice. It set out both a general minimum tariff <strong>and</strong> a<br />

24


maximum schedule to be paid by states that unreasonably discriminated against American<br />

exporters in the president's judgment. President Taft was then able to negotiate 23 agreements<br />

using the threat provided in the new law, ultimately declining to impose the maximum schedule<br />

on any state (Lake 1988, 131-6, 144-5; Taussig 1931, 403-5). While discrimination against<br />

American exports was to be punished, the Payne-Aldrich Tariff neither endorsed the<br />

unconditional interpretation of MFN nor ruled out further efforts to secure special privileges for<br />

American exports. Indeed, the Taft administration went on to negotiate such a trade agreement<br />

with Canada, though the Canadians ultimately declined to ratify it.<br />

American officials also sought access to foreign markets through less formal channels.<br />

<strong>Trade</strong> was a central preoccupation of American foreign policy before World War I. American<br />

diplomats as well as consuls worked to promote American exports. As the U.S. Minister to<br />

Brazil told a meeting on international trade in 1899, "it is no violation of proper diplomatic<br />

reserve to say that paramount in South America missions <strong>and</strong> consulates are the desire <strong>and</strong> effort<br />

to extend our commerce" (Butler 1899, 208). The failure of the McKinley administration's<br />

reciprocity treaties put a premium on other means for gaining market access. Hannigan (2002,<br />

65-6) points out that informal diplomatic efforts, as well as better marketing by American firms,<br />

became an increasingly important part of American plans to increase exports to Latin America<br />

during the Roosevelt administration. Congress also encouraged this approach, creating a Bureau<br />

of <strong>Foreign</strong> Commerce within the State Department in 1903 <strong>and</strong> increasing the Department's total<br />

staff by more than ten percent in the process (Plischke 1999, 206). In 1909, the Department<br />

reported that diplomatic intervention on behalf of American exporters "has increased at least 50<br />

percent in the last few years" (<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> Department of State 1909, 6).<br />

25


Further research, especially in the consular reports issued by American representatives<br />

abroad, is needed to determine the extent <strong>and</strong> specific effects of this diplomatic activity. The fact<br />

that U.S. representatives in the small states of the Caribbean basin had greater political resources<br />

than did their colleagues elsewhere permits a rough statistical test of whether it made a<br />

difference. The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> intervened in the Caribbean after 1898 far more often than in any<br />

other part of the world, occupying some countries for years at a time. Diplomats could use the<br />

specter of military intervention to threaten local authorities with whom they disagreed <strong>and</strong> to<br />

bolster those whom they preferred. Moreover, the American prohibition on intervention in the<br />

region by any other power effectively ruled out the assistance of any state powerful enough to<br />

challenge U.S. power in the region. These threats carried far less force in European colonies or in<br />

the large states of Colombia <strong>and</strong> Venezuela, where American intervention would have been far<br />

more costly. The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> also took control of customs revenue collection in some<br />

Caribbean states in several instances, such as in the Dominican Republic in 1904 <strong>and</strong> Nicaragua<br />

in 1912 (Hannigan 2002, 33-4, 42-3). These might also have provided opportunities for adjusting<br />

local tariff rates on American exports, as had been done in the Philippines. Writing in 1929,<br />

Benjamin Williams noted that "obtaining over certain countries a system of financial control<br />

backed by strong protection methods" had entirely supplanted any interest in further colonies<br />

because '[s]uch controls do not require annexation <strong>and</strong> do not affect trade through the<br />

manipulation of the tariffs" (B. H. Williams 1929, 330-1). If American diplomatic activity really<br />

made a difference, then the rate of growth in American exports to states in the region after the<br />

Spanish-American War should be faster than the rate of growth in American exports elsewhere<br />

<strong>and</strong> at other times.<br />

26


Figure 4 depicts the growth of American exports to independent states bordering on the<br />

Caribbean (excluding Venezuela <strong>and</strong> Colombia), as well as several comparison groups. Several<br />

patterns are consistent with effective intervention to promote these exports. First, exports to the<br />

Caribbean did not grow much more rapidly than did exports to Europe or the rest of the less<br />

developed world before 1898. The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> was far less active in the region before the<br />

Spanish American War <strong>and</strong> had fewer political <strong>and</strong> military resources at its disposal. Things<br />

changed after 1898, <strong>and</strong> especially after the 1903 announcement of the Roosevelt Corollary to<br />

the Monroe Doctrine, which codified the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>' more interventionist posture toward the<br />

region. American exports toward the Caribbean grew more rapidly than did exports toward than<br />

any of the comparison groups.<br />

[Figure 4 about here]<br />

Table 1 presents the results of a more formal statistical test of the hypothesis that<br />

American exports toward Caribbean states grew more rapidly. These models examine American<br />

exports to the countries <strong>and</strong> colonies for which the Commerce Department reported trade data.<br />

They treat the change in the annual value of American exports as a function of the lagged value<br />

of these exports, the lagged change, <strong>and</strong> a regional dummy variable for the Caribbean states after<br />

1898. The regional dummy tests the hypothesis that exports to these states grew more rapidly<br />

during this period. The other variables in the model capture the time dependence in each export<br />

series. The four models test the hypothesis that the Caribbean differed against four comparison<br />

groups: all states, Europe, other less developed areas, <strong>and</strong> European colonies in the Caribbean.<br />

[Table 1 about here.]<br />

The results suggest some qualifications to the patterns apparent in Figure 4 but they<br />

support the principal hypothesis. Exports to independent Caribbean states indeed increased more<br />

27


apidly after 1898 when compared to other less developed areas of the world, including other<br />

parts of the Caribbean. Annual growth in American exports to an average Caribbean state was<br />

about $410,000 greater than annual growth in exports to non-European states or colonies<br />

elsewhere. However, American exports to this part of the world did not increase more rapidly<br />

than did exports to Europe or, as a result, to the rest of the world as a whole. (European states<br />

made up a much larger share of the total number of states during this period than they do today,<br />

so they strongly influence the results for the world as a whole.) In spite of resentment of<br />

American commercial policy in Europe, it remained just as much of a dynamically increasing<br />

market for American exports after 1898 as the region in which the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> behaved most<br />

imperialistically. If American policy makers had wanted only to find growing export markets,<br />

this costly <strong>and</strong> controversial activity would have made little sense. However, the fact that<br />

American policy makers also cared about protecting their home market against manufactured<br />

exports also influenced their choices.<br />

The Broader Implications of the <strong>Protectionist</strong> Search for Markets<br />

Even if American policy makers had been able to set aside their commitment to trade protection,<br />

the search for export markets would still have had important foreign policy implications. For<br />

example, the effective pursuit of the Open Door in China might still have required an American<br />

naval presence in the region. Moreover, American policy makers would probably have seen first<br />

the Russians <strong>and</strong> later the Japanese as potential rivals in the region in view of these countries'<br />

efforts to set up their own exclusive economic <strong>and</strong> political spheres of influence there. 18 The<br />

18 At the time of the Open Door Notes, American observers identified Russia as the primary threat because of its<br />

newly acquired concessions in Manchuria (Hannigan 2002, 96-9). Examples of this concern from Forum alone<br />

include Low 1899; Cary 1898; Adams 1898; Moffett 1899; <strong>and</strong> W. C. Jameson Reid 1901. Japan was a potential<br />

ally against Russia. Reviewing press commentary in January 1904, the Literary Digest (American Sympathies in a<br />

28


British, who actually were committed to free trade during this period, generally perceived the<br />

same threats, <strong>and</strong> for much the same reason. The patterns of greatest interest here are those that<br />

would not have existed without the commitment to trade protection. The central role of markets<br />

in less-developed areas <strong>and</strong> the search for privileged access to these markets are direct practical<br />

implications of searching for overseas markets while protecting the domestic market. These<br />

uncooperative premises had broader <strong>and</strong> less direct effects on American foreign policy. They<br />

gave the emerging foreign policy an aggressive <strong>and</strong> opportunistic tone that accorded with<br />

arguments that international relations were fundamentally a zero-sum struggle for survival <strong>and</strong><br />

dominance. Those who rejected protectionism tended to see more opportunities for cooperation.<br />

These are precisely the dynamics Patrick McDonald suggests in his recent book linking<br />

protectionist to an aggressive foreign policy, which includes an excellent discussion of the<br />

American conflict with Britain over the Venezuelan border in 1895-6 (McDonald 2009, 155-84).<br />

The documentary evidence provides further support for this interpretation.<br />

Many observers at the time linked protectionism to a foreign policy that aggressively<br />

sought unilateral advantage at the expense of international cooperation. David Wells, a<br />

prominent advocate of free trade, argued that because tariffs harmed people in other states, they<br />

were essentially hostile acts. "Restrictions on the commercial intercourse of nations differ in<br />

form only from acts of war; <strong>and</strong> such acts inevitably tend to develop ill-feeling <strong>and</strong> acts of<br />

retaliation" (Wells 1891, 15). The writer William D. McCrackan made a similar argument two<br />

Russo-Japanese War 1904, 101) noted that "[n]ot a single newspaper in the country, as far as we have seen, favors<br />

anything but absolute neutrality in the dispute between Russia <strong>and</strong> Japan; but, at the same time, most of our press<br />

would like to see Japan win…. With Japan paramount, it is believed that American trade <strong>and</strong> influence in Asia<br />

would enjoy a rapid growth." However, once Japan defeated Russia, it became a greater potential threat to American<br />

interests. Press coverage quickly adjusted. The Literary Digest summarized articles citing Japanese efforts to<br />

monopolize commerce in areas they seized from Russia, calling for greater American efforts to preserve Chinese<br />

independence against Japan, <strong>and</strong> pointing out Japan's quest for commercial dominance in Asia (Menace of Japanese<br />

Success 1905, 920; Our Duty to Save China from Japan 1907, 288; Our Peaceful Contest with Japan 1907, 594).<br />

29


years later. "Under the plea of helping native industries, protection merely perpetuates bogus<br />

international hatreds. It destroys the brotherhood of nations. It brings estrangements, jealousies,<br />

imputations of evil motives, <strong>and</strong> misunderst<strong>and</strong>ings without end." 19 This line of argument was<br />

also common among scholars of international relations. For example, Paul Reinsch argued in his<br />

1900 textbook that "a growth of protectionist feeling <strong>and</strong> policy is going h<strong>and</strong> in h<strong>and</strong> with the<br />

growth of imperialism." He feared that protectionism would lead to "cutting the world up into<br />

mutually exclusive spheres, making trade national, <strong>and</strong> accentuating still further the excessive<br />

antagonisms between countries." 20<br />

Among observers who favored trade protection or took its presence for granted,<br />

commentary about the inevitability of political <strong>and</strong> military conflict over control of markets was<br />

common. Brooks Adams <strong>and</strong> Alfred Thayer Mahan are perhaps the best-remembered of those<br />

writing in this vein, but they were not alone. 21 For example, Charles Conant argued in a series of<br />

articles written soon after the Spanish-American War that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> would inevitably be<br />

drawn into a political-military contest for market access (Conant 1899, 1900a, 1900b). He noted<br />

that these means would not be necessary "[i]f commercial freedom were the rule among nations,"<br />

but argued that this had never really been the case (Conant 1900a, 608). Economic competition<br />

was commonly discussed in military terms as "peaceful combat," "conquer[ing] by commerce,"<br />

19<br />

McCrackan 1893, 145. McCrackan's article was summarized for a wider audience by Literary Digest (Our<br />

<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> 1893).<br />

20<br />

(Reinsch 1900, 38-9). Hobson (1965 [1902], 64-70) also linked imperialism <strong>and</strong> protectionism. Some textbooks<br />

written during the inter-war period also made the same connection (Moon 1936, 33-4; B. H. Williams 1929, 256-7).<br />

21 Adams' "The New Struggle for Life Among Nations" is a good example of his thinking (Adams 1900, 26-53).<br />

Mahan was less apocalyptic in tone because he wrote mainly about the past, even though he clearly intended his<br />

histories to serve as a guide for current policy makers. Nevertheless, he also viewed military competition for control<br />

of trade as a constant feature of human affairs. The Influence of Sea Power Upon History opens with the following<br />

observation about the benefits of seaborne commerce: "To secure one's own people a disproportionate share of such<br />

benefits, every effort was made to exclude others, either by the peace legislative methods of monopoly or<br />

prohibitory regulations, or when these failed, by direct violence" (Mahan 1987, 1).<br />

30


"peaceful conquest" <strong>and</strong> the like. 22 Then as now, advocates of free trade objected to these<br />

metaphors, arguing that trade was not a zero-sum endeavor. For example, Edward Atkinson<br />

wrote during the dispute with Britain over the Venezuelan border with British Guiana that "[t]he<br />

mediaeval error that in all commerce what one nation gains another must lose, is one of the most<br />

potent causes of the animosity against Engl<strong>and</strong> which now depraves the minds of many people in<br />

this country" (Atkinson 1896, 84). Republican policy makers nevertheless preferred the military<br />

metaphors. As one harsh but not entirely inaccurate Democratic critic summarized their<br />

perspective, "[i]ts spirit is that of conquest; its first reason, as well as its last, is force" (Gray<br />

1895, 424).<br />

The influence of protectionism on specific policy choices was apparent was in the<br />

changing interpretation of the Monroe Doctrine. Over the course of the 1890-1914 period,<br />

advocates of American empire reinterpreted this longst<strong>and</strong>ing policy in ways that complemented<br />

both the regional priorities <strong>and</strong> the emphasis on unilateral privilege associated with trade<br />

protection. 23 The Doctrine's prohibition on further European colonization undeniably involved a<br />

non-economic security interest in that a colony in the Caribbean Basin might have been used as a<br />

base from which to threaten the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>, or at least the proposed canal linking the Pacific<br />

Ocean <strong>and</strong> the Caribbean Sea. However, debate over whether potentially costly actions to<br />

enforce the Monroe Doctrine against European powers were worth the risk tended to divide<br />

22 These terms come from Eddy 1891, 421; Blaine 1892, 522; <strong>and</strong> Carter 1894, 431, respectively.<br />

23 Perhaps because they tended to take American security concerns less seriously, foreign observers linked the<br />

Monroe Doctrine <strong>and</strong> efforts to gain commercial control of the Western Hemisphere relatively early. The London<br />

Economist remarked on American efforts to establish "the Monroe doctrine in commerce for the whole Western<br />

Hemisphere" in 1886 (The Hide <strong>and</strong> Leather Industries 1886, 6). The Literary Digest summarized the comments of<br />

an Austrian legislator along the same lines in 1892: "The American policy is that of a great Power. Washington said<br />

to his countrymen: Take no part in European quarrels. Monroe came <strong>and</strong> said: No European state shall in the future<br />

found a new empire on this continent. Garfield <strong>and</strong> Blaine have gone a step beyond <strong>and</strong> said: The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> will<br />

extend its wings over the whole American continent, North <strong>and</strong> South, <strong>and</strong> will form a 'Zollverein' of the free<br />

countries of America" (The Commercial <strong>Policy</strong> of the World 1892, 647).<br />

31


protectionists, who were usually Republicans, from free traders, who were usually Democrats.<br />

From the protectionist point of view, Latin America was the most important potential target for<br />

the exclusive trading arrangements they hoped to construct. This effort would necessarily harm<br />

European commercial interests, perhaps leading to retaliation against American commercial<br />

interests elsewhere. Such conflict was less costly to protectionists because they were seeking to<br />

limit trade with Europe anyway. Free traders saw fewer benefits from trade with Latin America<br />

<strong>and</strong> much greater costs from conflict with European trading partners. Because the non-economic<br />

security implications of the Monroe Doctrine affected all Americans in roughly the same way,<br />

they cannot account for the strong divisions over what it meant <strong>and</strong> how it should be enforced.<br />

The relationship between the tariff <strong>and</strong> alternative views of the Monroe Doctrine was<br />

clearly on display during dispute over the Venezuelan boundary with British Guiana in 1895-6.<br />

The dispute was quite old, but the Venezuelan government hired an American publicist who<br />

substantially increased the visibility of the matter. It provoked an extensive debate in the <strong>United</strong><br />

<strong>States</strong> about what the Monroe Doctrine implied for American foreign policy. Because the <strong>United</strong><br />

<strong>States</strong> had no immediate stake in the boundary itself, the principal issue was whether British<br />

territorial claims violated the Monroe Doctrine <strong>and</strong> might justify an American military<br />

response. 24 Those who argued that it did frequently cited the importance of Latin America for<br />

the future of American commerce <strong>and</strong> thus the need to prevent Europeans from gaining or<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ing their foothold in the hemisphere. For example, two members of the House of<br />

Representatives, Joseph Wheeler (D-MS) <strong>and</strong> Charles Grosvenor (R-OH) wrote a joint article in<br />

24<br />

On the details of the crisis see (LaFeber 1963, 242-83; Hannigan 2002, 57-60; D. Healy 1970, 24-8; McDonald<br />

2009, 157-62), among others.<br />

32


the North American Review making the case for strong action against Britain. Both cited the<br />

commercial importance of the region as a key reason. 25<br />

Henry Cabot Lodge was among those offering the strongest interpretation of the Monroe<br />

Doctrine in this case (McDonald 2009, 168-71; Widenor 1980, 105-6). He asserted that the<br />

Doctrine gave the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> special prerogatives in the region, an area in which it held<br />

"rightful supremacy." The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> should be willing to fight to prevent any European<br />

power from seizing additional territory in the Americas. "The supremacy of the Monroe doctrine<br />

should be established <strong>and</strong> at once--peaceably if we can, forcibly if we must" (Lodge 1895a, 658).<br />

Lodge presented the Venezuela boundary dispute as a key example of the Clevel<strong>and</strong><br />

administration's broader policy of "retreat <strong>and</strong> surrender," an approach he linked to the<br />

Democratic Party's support for lower tariffs. He charged that Democrats had consistently failed<br />

to drive a sufficiently hard bargain in tariff negotiations with Canada <strong>and</strong> Germany, <strong>and</strong> had<br />

thrown away the advantages gained through Blaine's reciprocity treaties by abrogating them<br />

under the 1894 Wilson Tariff. Among those favoring free trade, he contended, "[e]verywhere<br />

there is opposition <strong>and</strong> abuse for the navy <strong>and</strong> sneers at any attempt to uphold the rights of the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> against any other nation." He also attacked free traders for their concerns about the<br />

costs of military conflict with Britain. "We have had something too much of these disciples of<br />

the Manchester School, who think the price of calico more important than a nation's honor, the<br />

duties on pig iron of more moment than the advance of the race" (Lodge 1895b, 8, 12-3, 14, 15).<br />

25 (Wheeler <strong>and</strong> Grosvenor 1895). Noting that Britain used its colonial possessions to extend its commerce Wheeler<br />

wrote that "far from receding from the strictest construction of the doctrine laid down by Monroe, my views are that<br />

the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> should extend its policy <strong>and</strong> look to the establishment of depots <strong>and</strong> naval stations around which<br />

American colonies would locate, sufficiently strong to encourage <strong>and</strong> protect our trade <strong>and</strong> commerce" (631). For<br />

his part, Grosvenor argued that "[a]t this time, Engl<strong>and</strong> seems to have special interest in South American affairs. Her<br />

efforts to secure trade belonging legitimately to her commercial rivals, have been supplemented by an interference in<br />

the Mosquito country which clearly manifests a disposition to control, if possible, the ownership of the great trans-<br />

Isthmus Canal. Engl<strong>and</strong> should not be permitted to succeed in this scheme. The building <strong>and</strong> control of that gigantic<br />

artery of international commerce should be the dearest object of American statesmanship" (633). The Literary<br />

Digest summarized this article for a broader audience (Our Duty in the Venezuelan Crisis 1895).<br />

33


Advocates of free trade viewed this dispute <strong>and</strong> broader prospects for cooperation with<br />

Britain very differently. Edward Atkinson, a New Engl<strong>and</strong> businessman <strong>and</strong> widely published<br />

supporter of free trade, responded to Lodge's arguments. Ridiculing Lodge's assertion that<br />

financial considerations could not be weighed against national honor, Atkinson wrote that "when<br />

it is proposed to dishonor the country by an aggressive <strong>and</strong> violent jingo policy without warrant<br />

of any kind, it becomes fit to count the cost of possible war in dollars <strong>and</strong> cents in order to bring<br />

the malignant influence of the jingo faction into most conspicuous notice" (Atkinson 1896, 74).<br />

He argued that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> gained far more from its close relationship with Britain than it<br />

could from increasing its trade with Latin America or other less developed areas of the world.<br />

Risking war with such a valuable trading partner was foolish. "The prosperity of the grain<br />

grower of the West, of the dairyman of the Middle <strong>States</strong>, <strong>and</strong> of the cotton grower in the South<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>s alike that every effort shall be asserted to overcome the prejudice <strong>and</strong> animosity which<br />

find their expression in jingoism." 26 Just as Lodge had tied the opposition to a hard-line position<br />

on Venezuela to support for free trade, Atkinson tied advocacy of war to protectionism:<br />

It is perfectly logical for the advocates of a prohibitory tariff to take the position<br />

long since taken by Henry C. Carey, who said that "he would regard a ten years'<br />

war with Engl<strong>and</strong> as the greatest material benefit that could happen to this<br />

country." People are wiser now than they were when they listened to such a false<br />

prophet, <strong>and</strong> yet there are to-day a sufficient number of ignorant persons to whom<br />

a similar appeal is made (Atkinson 1895, 558).<br />

David Wells, another well-known free trader, also joined the argument against Lodge <strong>and</strong><br />

other hard-liners during the dispute over the Venezuelan border. Writing in the North American<br />

Review, he focused on what he characterizes as the most important source of hostility to Britain:<br />

26 (Atkinson 1896, 82). Atkinson, who would go on to become a prominent figure in the anti-imperialist movement,<br />

later made much the same point about the limited value of American commerce with the Far East compared to the<br />

cost of subjugating the Philippines. "How other nations must laugh in their sleeves while witnessing what a fool<br />

Uncle Sam is making of himself at the present time, in the matter of military aggression under the pretext of<br />

expansion of commerce" (Atkinson 1900, 304).<br />

34


the belief that the country was seeking to monopolize wealth <strong>and</strong> commerce of the world at the<br />

expense of everyone else (Wells 1896, 387). After quoting a series of Republican speakers--<br />

including Lodge--making this charge, he argued that it fundamentally misunderstood British<br />

policy. Wells defended many aspects of British imperialism but focused special praise on their<br />

liberal commercial policy. Americans should pay attention to this issue in the Venezuelan case,<br />

Wells contended, because British commercial policy "is really the only involved point that<br />

materially affects their interest, <strong>and</strong> as such is more worthy of their serious consideration than<br />

any other" (401). Wells contended that Venezuela would restrict <strong>and</strong> tax commerce in the<br />

disputed area, while the British would not do so. He provocatively supported this claim by<br />

quoting an 1890 letter from the Venezuelan foreign minister to Secretary of State James Blaine,<br />

hinting that this well-known Republican defender of trade protection was sympathetic to sinister<br />

Venezuelan efforts to exclude foreign commerce (401-2). He concluded that the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong><br />

would actually be better off with the area under British than Venezuelan control <strong>and</strong> that the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> should pursue a more cooperative policy toward Britain in general (404-5).<br />

The regional priorities of the protectionists <strong>and</strong> free traders were also reflected to lesser<br />

extent in their attitude toward what most viewed as the Monroe Doctrine's natural correlate: non-<br />

entanglement in European political affairs. 27 Because nearly all Americans, including those who<br />

advocated free trade, took it for granted at the time that no such intervention would ever make<br />

sense, there was little debate on the issue. 28 As George Kennan (1984 [1951], 4-5) noted, the<br />

27 This injunction is clear enough in the plain language of the Monroe Doctrine, though it is not as widely discussed<br />

as the prohibition on European expansion in the Americas. "In the wars of the European powers in matters relating<br />

to themselves we have never taken any part, nor does it comport with our policy to do so."<br />

28 There is little evidence that this assumption changed until well after the outbreak of World War I. American<br />

leaders initially regarded the war in Europe with rather detached concern. Unlike most American diplomats, the U.S.<br />

consul in Budapest decided that the crisis of July 1914 was at least important enough to write about to Washington.<br />

However, he sent his message by regular mail out of concern about the cost of a cable transmission. It arrived on<br />

July 27, the day before the war began (West 1978, 1).<br />

35


dependence of American security on British power was not widely accepted before that time.<br />

Alfred Thayer Mahan worried about European colonial expansion in the Western Hemisphere,<br />

but he discounted the importance of conflicts in Europe, "whence, if disturbances arise, the effect<br />

upon us may be but partial <strong>and</strong> indirect" (Mahan 1897, 7). Lodge also ruled out American<br />

involvement in European conflicts in his discussion of the Monroe Doctrine during the<br />

Venezuelan boundary dispute. "The proposition laid down by Mr. Monroe, however, is not<br />

complicated. It is merely the corollary of Washington's neutrality policy, which declared that the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> would not meddle with or take part in the affairs of Europe." 29 The position Mahan<br />

<strong>and</strong> Lodge took on this issue certainly cannot be attributed to any general aversion to foreign<br />

policy activism.<br />

Contrary views about the possibility of American involvement in a European war were<br />

rare. There was occasional discussion of an alliance with Britain, but it is not clear whether those<br />

advocating this course anticipated involvement in a European war as a result. Not surprisingly,<br />

arguments for such an alliance were typically coupled with advocacy of free trade. Sidney<br />

Sherwood, a professor of economics at Johns Hopkins University, argued in the aftermath of the<br />

Venezuelan boundary dispute that the Monroe Doctrine no longer served American interests in<br />

an increasingly interdependent world where American manufactures required export markets<br />

(Sherwood 1896). Rather than seek colonies, he advocated a formal alliance with Britain coupled<br />

with a policy that would encourage British colonization in the Western Hemisphere in cases<br />

where it was required to preserve order. 30 Writing two years later, John Procter, who would later<br />

29 (Lodge 1895a, 651). Others writing on the Monroe Doctrine after the Venezuelan Crisis of 1895 took much the<br />

same position, arguing that it ruled out American intervention in Europe. See, for example, (R. E. Jones 1899;<br />

Chambers 1911; Taylor 1897; Moore 1896).<br />

30 Then as now, scholars like Sherwood could write what they liked, but questioning the Monroe Doctrine was<br />

dangerous for political leaders. For example, in 1906, Professor John W. Burgess gave a lecture in Germany arguing<br />

that both the Monroe Doctrine <strong>and</strong> the protective tariff were "almost obsolete." Burgess was a professor at Columbia<br />

36


serve as head of the Civil Service Commission under Theodore Roosevelt, similarly advocated<br />

setting aside the Monroe Doctrine in favor of an alliance with Britain. He also advocated a<br />

concomitant end to the protective tariff, "which is but one of the evils resulting from our policy<br />

of isolation" (Procter 1898, 23). 31 Whenever the topic arose, British observers tended to point to<br />

American protectionism as the main barrier to such an alliance (e.g., Smith 1898, 292; Mahan<br />

<strong>and</strong> Beresford 1894, 565-7).<br />

Overall, the policy of seeking special advantages for American exporters while closing<br />

the U.S. market to manufactured imports lent itself to an aggressive posture toward other states.<br />

This was particularly true in Latin America, which protectionists hoped to develop into an<br />

American sphere of economic influence. It is difficult to see how such uncooperative premises<br />

could have given rise to any other foreign policy. Those who rejected protectionism saw more<br />

promising avenues for international cooperation, especially with Britain, <strong>and</strong> remained puzzled<br />

by the stress on what they saw as relatively poor <strong>and</strong> unpromising markets. These debates<br />

reflected more than just differences in individual opinions. The association between free trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> cooperation--like that between protectionism <strong>and</strong> aggressive unilateralism--arose from the<br />

practical dem<strong>and</strong>s of these policies.<br />

University where he had founded Political Science Quarterly, <strong>and</strong> was then acting as Theodore Roosevelt Professor<br />

of American History <strong>and</strong> Institutions at the University of Berlin. His statements were reported in the American press<br />

<strong>and</strong> widely attacked by editorialists who mistakenly interpreted them as official policy. The administration quickly<br />

distanced itself from these comments, which reportedly caused the President so much irritation that "it probably<br />

could not be expressed in polite language" (A 'Roosevelt Professor's' Repudiation of the Monroe Doctrine 1906).<br />

31 Procter's article on the topic was part of a small flurry of discussion about an alliance with Britain after the<br />

Spanish-American War, in which Britain took a more favorable attitude toward the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> than did other<br />

powers. Editorials summarized in the Literary Digest include instances of support for the idea but also substantial<br />

opposition (Anglo-American Interests <strong>and</strong> Alliance 1898; The Chamberlain-Salisbury Anglo-American <strong>Policy</strong><br />

1898).<br />

37


Conclusion<br />

The evidence reviewed here suggests that the influence of international trade on American<br />

foreign policy before World War depended on both the dem<strong>and</strong> for foreign markets <strong>and</strong> the<br />

partisan conflict over the tariff. There was indeed widespread concern about access to foreign<br />

markets in elite discussion of American foreign policy. Setting aside the abstract question of<br />

whether it was necessary for the future of American capitalism, many influential people thought<br />

it would make the country more prosperous <strong>and</strong> favored policies to promote it. However, the<br />

policy implications of these dem<strong>and</strong>s for export markets depended on the position one took on<br />

trade protection. The dominant Republican Party's commitment to the protective tariff made<br />

markets in less developed areas more attractive to Republican leaders because products from<br />

these areas would not compete with American manufactures in the home market. For the same<br />

reason, the threat of European competition <strong>and</strong> tariff retaliation made markets there seem less<br />

promising to them. Broad tariff reductions were politically difficult for Republicans, so they<br />

preferred limited <strong>and</strong> exclusive bilateral trade concessions or, where possible, unilateral tariff<br />

reductions by trading partners. Multilateral arrangements based on unconditional most-favored<br />

nation status were not politically viable. These uncooperative economic premises encouraged a<br />

more aggressive foreign policy overall, including a willingness to take greater risks to keep<br />

European influence out of the Western Hemisphere.<br />

The implications of this review of American foreign policy debates before World War I<br />

are clear enough but many gaps in the evidence remain. The larger project of which this paper is<br />

part should help fill some of them. First, this paper reviews mainly evidence from public debate.<br />

This debate was more important before World War I than it is today because the state's capacity<br />

for secret (or even open) policy planning was far more limited then. Evidence from the policy<br />

38


making process within the state could still make a difference, though. Concerns about market<br />

access, often filtered through attitudes toward the tariff, were pervasive in the public debate.<br />

They might have been less important inside the state, especially within the military services<br />

because military officers were not usually directly involved in trade. Even though the military<br />

services were far smaller than they are today, there were still bodies like the Navy's General<br />

Board <strong>and</strong> the War Department's General Staff that had some capacity for policy planning<br />

(Challener 1973).<br />

Second, I have not yet tested the extent <strong>and</strong> durability of the association between trade<br />

protection <strong>and</strong> support for the foreign policy activism of the 1890-1914 period. The fact that<br />

Republicans tended to support both is clear enough, but my argument that trade protection was<br />

fundamental to the politics of American foreign policy during this period still needs to be tested<br />

systematically. There are no survey data on public opinion, of course, but there is plenty of<br />

evidence about elite attitudes from congressional debates <strong>and</strong> roll-call voting. Districts that were<br />

especially import-sensitive, especially with respect to Europe, should be more likely to elect<br />

members of Congress who were supportive of key elements of the foreign policy. Constituencies<br />

that depended heavily on manufacturing are likely to fit this description, but not all<br />

manufacturing industries were equally import-sensitive. For example, the 1901 debate within the<br />

National Association of Manufacturers over reciprocity treaties suggests that the representatives<br />

of the agricultural implements sector <strong>and</strong> a few others were willing to set aside their tariff<br />

protection in exchange for better access to European markets. Indications that export-oriented<br />

manufacturing was associated with declining support for foreign policy activism before 1914<br />

would provide especially strong support for the argument outlined here.<br />

39


Third, international trade was not the only economic issue with foreign policy<br />

implications during this period. There was of course also a debate over the gold st<strong>and</strong>ard that had<br />

important consequences for American integration into the world economy. Like trade, adherence<br />

to the gold st<strong>and</strong>ard had distributive effects within the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> as well as implications for<br />

the country's relations with other states. For example, Jeff Frieden has argued that ab<strong>and</strong>oning<br />

the gold st<strong>and</strong>ard would have raised the price of tradable goods relative to non-tradable goods<br />

within the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> (Frieden 1997). Adherence to the gold st<strong>and</strong>ard thus served the interests<br />

of the same domestically oriented manufacturers who benefited most from trade protection <strong>and</strong><br />

the relatively aggressive foreign policy agenda associated with it. Nevertheless, McDonald<br />

(2009, 171-6) points out that advocates of monetizing silver took a more belligerent posture<br />

toward Britain during the Venezuelan boundary dispute, suggesting that monetary policy<br />

interests might have differed from those implied by trade in some cases. Sorting out the foreign<br />

policy implications of monetary policy merits the same kind of attention that I have offered for<br />

trade <strong>and</strong> trade policy here.<br />

Because the evidence is incomplete, firm conclusions about what it tells us about<br />

American foreign policy would be premature. However, some observations about the analytical<br />

stakes are still possible. If the patterns suggested here hold up to closer scrutiny, they will reveal<br />

a striking discontinuity between the foreign policy activism of the pre-1914 period <strong>and</strong> the<br />

superficially similar activism of the years since 1945. <strong>Policy</strong> makers during both periods built up<br />

American military power <strong>and</strong> sought a larger political role for the country in world politics. A<br />

consideration of the role of trade protection suggests the limits of these similarities. While<br />

protectionists were the main supporters of the foreign policy activism of the 1890-1914 period,<br />

those with an interest in free trade have been the principal backers of American internationalism<br />

40


in the postwar era (Fordham 2008a, 2008b). Given the content of the policy, this reversal is not<br />

surprising. After World War II, the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> worked to promote more liberal trade policies<br />

worldwide <strong>and</strong> helped establish a multilateral trading system based on the unconditional<br />

interpretation of most-favored nation status. Indeed, some have argued that the nation's<br />

commitment to these <strong>and</strong> other multilateral institutions is the distinguishing feature of American<br />

hegemony (e.g., Ikenberry 2001). 32 The logical successor to the foreign policy activism of the<br />

1890-1914 period appears to be not the internationalism of the postwar era but rather the<br />

isolationism of the interwar years.<br />

This discontinuity casts doubt on explanations for the development of American foreign<br />

policy that stress broadly or universally shared ideas or interests. These accounts have difficulty<br />

explaining policy debates <strong>and</strong> policy changes. There were indeed many points of near-<br />

unanimous consensus among those writing about American foreign policy during the 1890-1914<br />

period. For example, nearly all of them agreed that American institutions were great <strong>and</strong><br />

exceptional <strong>and</strong> that there was a hierarchy of races, with people like themselves at the top.<br />

However, these shared ideas did not lead them to agree on the policy issues before them. This<br />

explanatory difficult also extends to argument emphasizing shared national interests rather than<br />

ideas. These shared interests do not provide a basis for disagreement <strong>and</strong> debate. To the extent<br />

that policy choice hinges on the outcome of a policy debate, with the winning side implementing<br />

its priorities, explanations that cannot account for the differences of opinion will be<br />

indeterminate.<br />

32 Of course, some American leaders have remained skeptical about these institutional commitments just as others<br />

had remained skeptical of the imperialism of the 1890-1914 period. Given their party's policy commitments before<br />

1914, it is not surprising us that resistance to postwar American institutional commitments has come primarily from<br />

Republicans. It is worth noting that many policy makers still active in the 1940s <strong>and</strong> 1950s would have had no<br />

trouble remembering the years before 1914. Even though the Republican preference for trade protection was fading<br />

by the late 1940s (Irwin <strong>and</strong> Kroszner 1999; Fordham 1998), it retained vestiges of its former policy commitments<br />

during the construction of the postwar order.<br />

41


Arguments about broad continuities are common in the historiography of American<br />

foreign relations. The Wisconsin School's overemphasis on the consensus about the need for<br />

foreign markets is an important critique of this perspective (e.g., Thompson 1973, 102-4; Field<br />

1978, 645-6). The contrast between the foreign policy of the post-World War II <strong>and</strong> pre-World<br />

War I eras suggest that this criticism is well taken. Agreement on the desirability of foreign<br />

markets was only the beginning of the story, <strong>and</strong> "open-door imperialism" is probably a better<br />

description of American foreign policy after 1945 than before 1914. The Wisconsin School used<br />

this continuity to support a left critique of American foreign policy, what James Field (1978,<br />

645) aptly called an "inverted Whig interpretation of history, differing from its predecessor in<br />

that now the children of darkness triumph over the children of light." Appealing to false<br />

continuities in American foreign policy knows no ideological bounds, however. Since the 9/11<br />

terrorist attacks many historical accounts have found echoes of the key features of current<br />

American foreign policy such as the promotion of democracy or the country's periodic<br />

involvement in small wars to earlier periods of American history (e.g., Boot 2003; Kagan 2006).<br />

These accounts support a conservative effort to give the Bush administration's foreign policy the<br />

luster <strong>and</strong> legitimacy of longst<strong>and</strong>ing tradition instead of being a radical new departure.<br />

Regardless of their ideological bent, arguments that American foreign policy is rooted in some<br />

set of ideas or interests that have remained consistent over time are likely to obscure more than<br />

they reveal. If this alleged continuity, whatever its roots, can produce policies that differ as<br />

radically as that of 1890-1914 differed from what came after 1945, then it probably does not<br />

explain much.<br />

42


References<br />

A 'Roosevelt Professor's' Repudiation of the Monroe Doctrine. 1906. Literary Digest 33(19):<br />

664-5.<br />

Adams, Brooks. 1900. America's Economic Supremacy. New York: The Macmillan Company.<br />

Adams, Brooks. 1898. "The Spanish War <strong>and</strong> the Equilibrium of the World." Forum 25(6): 641-<br />

51.<br />

America <strong>and</strong> Joseph Chamberlain. 1903. Literary Digest 27(16): 493-4.<br />

America <strong>and</strong> Protection. 1890. Literary Digest 2(5): 113-4.<br />

American Imperialism as Viewed Abroad. 1901. Literary Digest 23(11): 320-2.<br />

American Sympathies in a Russo-Japanese War. 1904. Literary Digest 28(4): 101-2.<br />

Anglo-American Interests <strong>and</strong> Alliance. 1898. Literary Digest 16(18): 511-3.<br />

Atkinson, Edward. 1900. "Eastern Commerce: What Is It Worth?." North American Review<br />

170(519): 295-304.<br />

Atkinson, Edward. 1895. "Jingoes <strong>and</strong> Silverites." North American Review 161(468): 554-560.<br />

Atkinson, Edward. 1896. "The Cost of an Anglo-American War." Forum 21(1): 74-88.<br />

Bailey, Michael A., Judith Goldstein, <strong>and</strong> Barry R. Weingast. 1997. "The Institutional Roots of<br />

American <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: Politics, Coalitions, <strong>and</strong> International <strong>Trade</strong>." World Politics<br />

49(3): 309-338.<br />

Bensel, Richard Franklin. 2000. The Political Economy of American Industrialization, 1877-<br />

1900. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Blaine, James G. 1892. "The Presidential Election of 1892." North American Review 155(432):<br />

513-525.<br />

Boot, Max. 2003. The Savage Wars of Peace: Small Wars <strong>and</strong> the Rise of American Power. New<br />

York: Basic Books.<br />

Brooks, Sydney. 1901. "American Imperialism." Fortnightly Review 70(416): 226-328.<br />

Butler, William Mill, ed. 1899. Official Proceedings of the International Commercial Congress;<br />

a Conference of All Nations for the Extension of Commercial Intercourse. Philadelphia:<br />

Press of the Philadelphia Commercial Museum.<br />

43


Carr, William. 1972. Arms, Autarky <strong>and</strong> Aggression: A Study in German <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, 1933-<br />

1939. London: Edward Arnold.<br />

Carter, Susan B. et al., eds. 2006. Historical Statistics of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>: Earliest Times to the<br />

Present. Millennial ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Carter, Thomas H. 1894. "The Republican Outlook." North American Review 158(449): 423-<br />

432.<br />

Cary, Clarence. 1898. "China's Complications <strong>and</strong> American <strong>Trade</strong>." Forum 25(1): 35-45.<br />

Challener, Richard D. 1973. Admirals, Generals, <strong>and</strong> American <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, 1898-1914.<br />

Princeton: Princeton University Press.<br />

Chambers, Julius. 1911. "The Monroe Doctrine in the Balance." Forum 46(5): 525-35.<br />

Clark, John Bates. 1907. "Inexpensive Reciprocity." Forum 38(3): 413-23.<br />

Coatsworth, John H., <strong>and</strong> Jeffrey G. Williamson. 2004. "Always <strong>Protectionist</strong>? Latin American<br />

<strong>Tariffs</strong> from Independence to Great Depression." Journal of Latin American Studies<br />

36(2): 205-232.<br />

Conant, Charles A. 1899. "The Struggle for Commercial <strong>Empire</strong>." Forum 27(4): 427-40.<br />

Conant, Charles A. 1900a. "The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> as a World Power, I. The Nature of the Economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> Political Problem." Forum 29(5): 608-22.<br />

Conant, Charles A. 1900b. "The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> as a World Power, II. Her Advantages in the<br />

Struggle for Commercial <strong>Empire</strong>." Forum 29(6): 673-87.<br />

Crowley, James B. 1966. Japan's Quest for Autonomy; National Security <strong>and</strong> <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

1930-1938. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.<br />

Culbertson, William Smith. 1919. "The "Open Door" <strong>and</strong> Colonial <strong>Policy</strong>." American Economic<br />

Review 9(1): 325-340.<br />

Eddy, Ulysses D. 1892. "My Business Partner, the Government." Forum 13(3): 379-88.<br />

Eddy, Ulysses D. 1891. "Our Chance for Commercial Supremacy." Forum 11(4): 419-28.<br />

Epstein, David, <strong>and</strong> Sharyn O'Halloran. 1996. "The Partisan Paradox <strong>and</strong> the U.S. Tariff, 1877-<br />

1934." International Organization 50(2): 301-324.<br />

Field, James A. 1978. "American Imperialism: The Worst Chapter in Almost Any Book."<br />

American Historical Review 83(3): 644-668.<br />

44


Findlay, Ronald, <strong>and</strong> Kevin H O'Rourke. 2007. Power <strong>and</strong> Plenty: <strong>Trade</strong>, War, <strong>and</strong> the World<br />

Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton, N.J: Princeton University Press.<br />

Flint, Charles R. 1897. "Our Export <strong>Trade</strong>." Forum 23(3): 290-7.<br />

Ford, Worthington C. 1898. "Commercial Superiority of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>." North American<br />

Review 166(494): 75-84.<br />

Ford, Worthington C. 1899. "The Commercial Relations of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> with the Far East."<br />

Annals of the American Academy of Political <strong>and</strong> Social Science 13(Supplement): 107-<br />

30.<br />

Fordham, Benjamin O. 2008a. "Economic Interests <strong>and</strong> Congressional Voting on American<br />

<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>." Journal of Conflict Resolution 52(5): 623-40.<br />

Fordham, Benjamin O. 2008b. "Economic Interests <strong>and</strong> Public Support for American Global<br />

Activism." International Organization 62(1): 163-182.<br />

Fordham, Benjamin O. 1998. "Economic Interests, Party, <strong>and</strong> Ideology in Early Cold War Era<br />

U.S. <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>." International Organization 52(2): 359-396.<br />

French Comment on the Tariff Bill. 1890. Literary Digest 2(2): 50.<br />

Frieden, Jeffry A. 1997. "Monetary Populism in Nineteenth-Century America: An Open<br />

Economy Interpretation." Journal of Economic History 57(2): 367-395.<br />

Gallagher, John, <strong>and</strong> Ronald Robinson. 1953. "The Imperialism of Free <strong>Trade</strong>." Economic<br />

History Review 6(1): 1-15.<br />

Gibson, E. J. 1901. "Reciprocity <strong>and</strong> <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Trade</strong>." Forum 32(4): 466-80.<br />

Gladstone, W. E., <strong>and</strong> James G. Blaine. 1890. "A Duel. Free <strong>Trade</strong>: The Right Hon. W. E.<br />

Gladstone. Protection: The Hon. James G. Blaine." North American Review 150(398): 1-<br />

54.<br />

Goldstein, Judith. 1993. Ideas, Interests, <strong>and</strong> American <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>. Ithaca: Cornell University<br />

Press.<br />

Gore, James Howard. 1899. "The Commercial Relations of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>and</strong> Germany."<br />

Forum 28(4): 493-502.<br />

Gray, George. 1895. "Two Years of American Diplomacy." North American Review 160(461):<br />

409-424.<br />

Hannigan, Robert E. 2002. The New World Power: American <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, 1898-1917.<br />

Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.<br />

45


Healy, A. Augustus. 1893. "Necessity for Immediate Tariff Reduction." Forum 16(4): 405-12.<br />

Healy, David. 1970. US Expansionism; the Imperialist Urge in the 1890s. Madison: University<br />

of Wisconsin Press.<br />

Herbert, Hilary A. 1892. "Reciprocity <strong>and</strong> the Farmer." North American Review 154(425): 414-<br />

423.<br />

Hill, Robert T. 1899. "The Commercial Relations of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> with the Far East." Annals<br />

of the American Academy of Political <strong>and</strong> Social Science 13(Supplement): 131-42.<br />

Hobson, John Atkinson. 1965 [1902]. Imperialism: A Study. Ann Arbor, MI: University of<br />

Michigan Press.<br />

Hobson, John Atkinson. 1894. The Evolution of Modern Capitalism. A Study of Machine<br />

Production. New York: Charles Scribner's Sons.<br />

Hoxie, R. F. 1903. "The American Colonial <strong>Policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Tariff." Journal of Political Economy<br />

11(2): 198-219.<br />

Ikenberry, G. John. 2001. After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, <strong>and</strong> the Rebuilding of<br />

Order After Major Wars. Princeton: Princeton University Press.<br />

Irwin, Douglas A., <strong>and</strong> R<strong>and</strong>all S. Kroszner. 1999. "Interests, Institutions, <strong>and</strong> Ideology in<br />

Securing <strong>Policy</strong> Change: The Republican Conversion to <strong>Trade</strong> Liberalization After<br />

Smoot‐Hawley." Journal of Law <strong>and</strong> Economics 42(2): 643-674.<br />

Jones, Chester Lloyd. 1908. "The American Interpretation of the "Most Favored Nation"<br />

Clause." Annals of the American Academy of Political <strong>and</strong> Social Science 32: 119-129.<br />

Jones, Robert Ellis. 1899. "Washington's Farewell Address <strong>and</strong> Its Applications." Forum 28(1):<br />

13-28.<br />

Kagan, Robert. 2006. Dangerous Nation. New York: Knopf.<br />

Kennan, George F. 1984 [1951]. American Diplomacy. Exp<strong>and</strong>ed edition. Chicago: University of<br />

Chicago Press.<br />

LaFeber, Walter. 1963. The New <strong>Empire</strong>: An Interpretation of American Expansion, 1860-1898.<br />

Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.<br />

Lake, David A. 1988. Power, Protection, <strong>and</strong> Free <strong>Trade</strong>: International Sources of U.S.<br />

Commercial Strategy, 1887-1939. Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell University Press.<br />

Laughlin, J. Laurence, <strong>and</strong> H. Parker Willis. 1903. Reciprocity. New York: The Baker & Taylor<br />

46


Company.<br />

Litman, Simon. 1909. "Tariff Revision <strong>and</strong> <strong>Foreign</strong> Markets." American Economic Association<br />

Quarterly 10(1): 314-325.<br />

Lodge, Henry Cabot. 1895a. "Engl<strong>and</strong>, Venezuela, <strong>and</strong> the Monroe Doctrine." North American<br />

Review 160(463): 651-658.<br />

Lodge, Henry Cabot. 1895b. "Our Blundering <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>." Forum 19(1): 8-17.<br />

Low, A. Maurice. 1899. "Russia, Engl<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>." Forum 28(2): 172-81.<br />

Mahan, Alfred Thayer. 1987 [1890]. The Influence of Sea Power Upon History, 1660-1783. New<br />

York: Dover Publications.<br />

Mahan, Alfred Thayer. 1897. The Interest of America in Sea Power, Present <strong>and</strong> Future. Boston:<br />

Little, Brown <strong>and</strong> Company.<br />

Mahan, Alfred Thayer, <strong>and</strong> Charles Beresford. 1894. "Possibilities of an Anglo-American<br />

Reunion." North American Review 159(456): 551-573.<br />

McCormick, Thomas J. 1967. China Market; America's Quest for Informal <strong>Empire</strong>, 1893-1901.<br />

Chicago: Quadrangle Books.<br />

McCrackan, W. D. 1893. "Our <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>." Arena (44): 145-50.<br />

McDonald, Patrick J. 2009. The Invisible H<strong>and</strong> of Peace: Capitalism, the War Machine, <strong>and</strong><br />

International Relations Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

McKinley, William. 1890. "The Value of Protection." North American Review 150(403): 740-<br />

748.<br />

Medley, George W. 1893. "A New Era for the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>." Forum 15(1): 24-30.<br />

Menace of Japanese Success. 1905. Literary Digest 30(25): 920-1.<br />

Mills, Roger Q. 1891. "Reciprocity-Why Southward Only?." Forum 11(3): 268-75.<br />

Mills, Roger Q. 1890. "The Gladstone-Blaine Controversy." North American Review 150(399):<br />

145-176.<br />

Mills, Roger Q. 1894. "The Wilson Bill." North American Review 158(447): 235-244.<br />

Milward, Alan S. 1977. War, Economy, <strong>and</strong> Society, 1939-1945. Berkeley: University of<br />

California Press.<br />

47


Moffett, Samuel E. 1899. "Ultimate World-Politics." Forum 27(6): 665-8.<br />

de Molinari, Gustave. 1890. "The McKinley Bill in Europe." North American Review 151(406):<br />

307-318.<br />

Moon, Parker Thomas. 1936. Imperialism <strong>and</strong> World Politics. New York: The Macmillan<br />

Company.<br />

Moore, John Bassett. 1896. "The Monroe Doctrine." Political Science Quarterly 11(1): 1-29.<br />

Narizny, Kevin. 2007. The Political Economy of Gr<strong>and</strong> Strategy. Ithaca: Cornell University<br />

Press.<br />

National Association of Manufacturers. 1901. Proceedings of the National Reciprocity<br />

Convention Held Under the Auspices of the National Association of Manufacturers of the<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> of America. Washington, D.C.: National Association of Manufacturers.<br />

Net Results of the Reciprocity Convention. 1901. Literary Digest 23(22): 675-6.<br />

Our Commercial Growth <strong>and</strong> the Tariff: A Republican View. 1892. Literary Digest 6(3): 57-8.<br />

Our Duty in the Venezuelan Crisis. 1895. Literary Digest 12(2): 34.<br />

Our Duty to Save China from Japan. 1907. Literary Digest 35(9): 288.<br />

Our <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>. 1893. Literary Digest 7(11): 281-2.<br />

Our Peaceful Contest with Japan. 1907. Literary Digest 35(17): 594.<br />

Peterson, Theodore Bernard. 1964. Magazines in the Twentieth Century. 2nd ed. Urbana:<br />

University of Illinois Press.<br />

Plischke, Elmer. 1999. U.S. Department of State: A Reference History. Westport, Conn:<br />

Greenwood Press.<br />

Procter, John R. 1893. "America's Battle for Commercial Supremacy." Forum 16(3): 315-24.<br />

Procter, John R. 1898. "Isolationism or Imperialism." Forum 26(1): 14-26.<br />

Protectionism in the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. 1891. Literary Digest 3(12): 309.<br />

Reid, W. C. Jameson. 1901. "The Political <strong>and</strong> Commercial Future of Asia." Forum 32(3): 341-<br />

54.<br />

Reid, Whitelaw. 1900. Problems of Expansion, as Considered in Papers <strong>and</strong> Addresses. New<br />

York: The Century Company.<br />

48


Reinsch, Paul Samuel. 1900. World Politics at the End of the Nineteenth Century. New York:<br />

The Macmillan Company.<br />

Republican Opposition to President Roosevelt. 1905. Literary Digest 31(16): 519-20.<br />

Schoenhof, Jacob. 1898. "Exports <strong>and</strong> Wages." Forum 24(5): 540-52.<br />

Schoenhof, Jacob. 1902. "The Rake's Progress in Tariff Legislation." Forum 29(5): 608-22.<br />

Selbie, William. 1893. "Our Coming Rival." North American Review 157(441): 254-256.<br />

Shall America Join in the Partition of China? 1900. Literary Digest 21(9): 241-3.<br />

Sherwood, Sidney. 1896. "An Alliance with Engl<strong>and</strong> the Basis of a Rational <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>."<br />

Forum 21(1): 89-100.<br />

Smith, Goldwin. 1898. "The Moral of the Cuban War." Forum 26(3): 282-93.<br />

Speck, Mary. 2005. "Closed-Door Imperialism: The Politics of Cuban-U. S. <strong>Trade</strong>, 1902-1933."<br />

Hispanic American Historical Review 85(3): 449-483.<br />

Taussig, F. W. 1910. The Tariff History of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. 5th ed. New York: G. P. Putnam's<br />

Sons.<br />

Taussig, F. W. 1931. The Tariff History of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. 8th ed. New York: G. P. Putnam's<br />

Sons.<br />

Taylor, Hannis. 1897. "A Review of the Cuban Question in Its Economic, Political, <strong>and</strong><br />

Diplomatic Aspects." North American Review 165(492): 610-635.<br />

Terrill, Tom E. 1973. The Tariff, Politics, <strong>and</strong> American <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>, 1874-1901. Westport,<br />

Conn: Greenwood Press.<br />

The American Tariff War. 1890. Literary Digest 2(1): 2.<br />

The American Tariff--Past <strong>and</strong> Future. 1892. Literary Digest 6(8): 197.<br />

The Chamberlain-Salisbury Anglo-American <strong>Policy</strong>. 1898. Literary Digest 16(22): 634-7.<br />

The Commercial <strong>Policy</strong> of the World. 1892. Literary Digest 4(24): 647-8.<br />

The Hide <strong>and</strong> Leather Industries. 1886. The Economist: 6-7.<br />

The McKinley Bill. 1890. Literary Digest 2(6): 141.<br />

49


The McKinley Bill in Europe. 1890. Literary Digest 1(22): 590.<br />

The Open Door. 1898. Literary Digest 17(24): 680-2.<br />

The Ruin of the American Farmer. 1892. Literary Digest 6(5): 113-4.<br />

The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Open Door. 1900. The Economist: 2.<br />

The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> as a World Power. 1899. Literary Digest 18(1): 21-2.<br />

Thompson, J. A. 1973. "William Appleman Williams <strong>and</strong> the 'American <strong>Empire</strong>'." Journal of<br />

American Studies 7(1): 91-104.<br />

Topik, Steven. 1996. <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Gunboats: The <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> <strong>and</strong> Brazil in the Age of <strong>Empire</strong>.<br />

Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.<br />

Trask, David F. 1981. A Short History of the U.S. Department of State, 1781-1981. Washington,<br />

D.C: U.S. Dept. of State, Bureau of Public Affairs, Office of Public Communications.<br />

Trubowitz, Peter. 1998. Defining the National Interest: Conflict <strong>and</strong> Change in American<br />

<strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.<br />

U.S. National Archives <strong>and</strong> Records Administration. 2011. "U. S. Electoral College." Available<br />

at: http://www.archives.gov/federal-register/electoral-college/historical.html [Accessed<br />

February 13, 2011].<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> Census Bureau. 1901. "1900 Census of Population <strong>and</strong> Housing." 1900 Census of<br />

Population <strong>and</strong> Housing. Available at:<br />

http://www.census.gov/prod/www/abs/decennial/1900.html [Accessed February 25,<br />

2011].<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> Department of State. 1909. <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> Treaty Relations. [Washington:<br />

Govt. print. off.<br />

<strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong> Senate. 1902. Correspondence Relating to Philippine Customs Tariff. Washington,<br />

D.C.: Government Printing Office.<br />

Vest, George G. 1892. "The Real Issue." North American Review 155(431): 401-406.<br />

Viner, Jacob. 1924. "The Most-Favored-Nation Clause in American Commercial Treaties."<br />

Journal of Political Economy 32(1): 101-129.<br />

Wells, David A. 1896. "Great Britain <strong>and</strong> the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>: Their True Relations." North<br />

American Review 162(473): 385-405.<br />

Wells, David A. 1891. "Protection or Free <strong>Trade</strong>--Which?." Arena (25): 12-23.<br />

50


West, Rachel. 1978. The Department of State on the Eve of the First World War. Athens:<br />

University of Georgia Press.<br />

Wheeler, Joseph, <strong>and</strong> Charles H. Grosvenor. 1895. "Our Duty in the Venezuelan Crisis." North<br />

American Review 161(468): 628-633.<br />

Widenor, William C. 1980. Henry Cabot Lodge <strong>and</strong> the Search for an American <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>.<br />

Berkeley: University of California Press.<br />

Williams, Benjamin Harrison. 1929. Economic <strong>Foreign</strong> <strong>Policy</strong> of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>. New York:<br />

McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc.<br />

Williams, William Appleman. 2009 [1959]. The Tragedy of American Diplomacy. 50th<br />

anniversary edition. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.<br />

Wilson, William L. 1894. "The Principle <strong>and</strong> Method of the New Tariff Bill." Forum 16(6): 544-<br />

9.<br />

Wilson, William L. 1892. "The Republican <strong>Policy</strong> of Reciprocity." Forum 14(2): 255-64.<br />

Wolman, Paul. 1992. Most Favored Nation: The Republican Revisionists <strong>and</strong> U.S. Tariff <strong>Policy</strong>,<br />

1897-1912. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.<br />

Young, John P. 1899. "Will Chinese Development Benefit the Western World?." Forum 28(3):<br />

348-62.<br />

51


Table 1.<br />

Models of Annual Change in American Exports to Selected Areas of the World, 1870-1913<br />

All states Europe<br />

Comparison Group:<br />

Other lessdeveloped<br />

areas<br />

0.02*<br />

(0.01)<br />

-0.04<br />

(0.02)<br />

0.41*<br />

(0.16)<br />

0.09*<br />

52<br />

European<br />

colonies in the<br />

Caribbean<br />

0.02*<br />

(0.01)<br />

0.18*<br />

(0.06)<br />

0.39*<br />

Exportst-1<br />

0.02* 0.02*<br />

(0.002) (0.004)<br />

Change in Exports t-1<br />

-0.16* -0.17*<br />

(0.02) (0.03)<br />

Independent Caribbean<br />

0.20 -0.53<br />

State, 1899-1913<br />

(0.60) (1.05)<br />

(0.20)<br />

Constant 0.41* 1.17*<br />

-0.03<br />

(0.14) (0.45) (0.05) (0.13)<br />

R-squared 0.04 0.04 0.01 0.10<br />

Number of states 70 29 51 15<br />

Observations 2,606 927 1,822 330<br />

Note: OLS coefficients with st<strong>and</strong>ard errors in parentheses. Asterisk indicates statistical<br />

significance at the p < 0.05 level. The dependent variable is the annual change in American<br />

exports to each state or colony for which data reported in the Statistical Abstract of the <strong>United</strong><br />

<strong>States</strong>, in millions of 1900 dollars.


Percent of Total Exports<br />

40%<br />

35%<br />

30%<br />

25%<br />

20%<br />

15%<br />

10%<br />

5%<br />

Figure 1.<br />

U.S. Exports by Selected Commodities<br />

Cotton<br />

Tobacco <strong>and</strong> wheat<br />

Automobiles, iron <strong>and</strong> steel,<br />

<strong>and</strong> machinery<br />

0%<br />

1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915<br />

Source: Historical Statistics of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>


$77<br />

$48<br />

$73<br />

$19<br />

$24<br />

$105<br />

$30<br />

Value-Added Per Capita<br />

$0 to $25<br />

$25 to $50<br />

$50 to $100<br />

$100 to $205<br />

$100<br />

$26<br />

$67<br />

Figure 2.<br />

Manufacturing Activity by State, 1900<br />

$11<br />

$11<br />

$7<br />

$14 $16<br />

$17<br />

$39<br />

$29<br />

$51<br />

$28<br />

$55<br />

$28<br />

$44<br />

$108<br />

$12<br />

$65<br />

$65<br />

$19<br />

$20<br />

$33<br />

$93<br />

$22<br />

$81<br />

$33<br />

$18<br />

$22<br />

$40<br />

$126<br />

$31<br />

$127<br />

$142<br />

$83<br />

$84<br />

$133<br />

$101<br />

$172<br />

$205<br />

$184


Percent of Total Exports<br />

100%<br />

80%<br />

60%<br />

40%<br />

20%<br />

0%<br />

Figure 3.<br />

U.S. Exports by Region of Destination, 1866-1914<br />

Americas<br />

Europe<br />

Asia<br />

Other<br />

1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915<br />

Source: Historical Statistics of the <strong>United</strong> <strong>States</strong>


Index of U.S. Exports to Region<br />

(1870=1.00)<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

Figure 4.<br />

Growth in U.S. Exports by Region<br />

Less-developed areas other than Caribbean<br />

Caribbean states<br />

Developed states<br />

Caribbean colonies of European states<br />

1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!