05.06.2013 Views

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

FRAMEWORK AND GUIDING PRINCIPLES FOR THE POLICY RESPONSE<br />

Box 2.3 provides examples of how economic information<br />

can be applied at decision-making stage.<br />

Box 2.4 illustrates the use of economic valuation at a<br />

later stage, after damage has occurred, to guide legal<br />

remedies and the award of compensation.<br />

Box 2.3: Using valuation as part of a decision<br />

support system<br />

Indonesia: the Segah watershed (Berau District)<br />

contains some of the largest tracts of undisturbed<br />

lowland forest in East Kalimantan (150,000 hectares)<br />

which provide the last substantial orang-utan habitat.<br />

A 2002 valuation study concluded that water<br />

from the Segah river and the nearby Kelay river had<br />

an estimated value of more than US$ 5.5<br />

million/year (e.g. regulation of water flow rates and<br />

sediment loads to protect infrastructure and<br />

irrigation systems). In response to these findings, the<br />

Segah Watershed Management Committee was<br />

established to protect the watershed.<br />

Source: The Nature Conservancy 2007<br />

Uganda: the Greater City of Kampala benefits from<br />

services provided by the Nakivubo Swamp (catchment<br />

area > 40 km²) which cleans water polluted<br />

by industrial, urban and untreated sewage waste.<br />

A valuation study looked at the cost of replacing<br />

wetland wastewater processing services with artificial<br />

technologies (i.e. upgraded sewage treatment<br />

plant, construction of latrines to process sewage<br />

from nearby slums). It concluded that the infrastructure<br />

required to achieve a similar level of<br />

wastewater treatment to that naturally provided by<br />

the wetland would cost up to US$2 million/year c.f.<br />

the costs of managing the natural wetland to<br />

optimise its waste treatment potential and maintain<br />

its ecological integrity (about US$ 235,000). on the<br />

basis of this economic argument, plans to drain and<br />

reclaim the wetland were reversed and Nakivubo<br />

was legally designated as part of the city’s greenbelt<br />

zone.<br />

Sources: Emerton and Bos 2004;<br />

UNDP-UNEP Poverty-Environment Facility 2008<br />

Box 2.4: Economic valuation of damages<br />

to enforce liability rules<br />

The accident of the Exxon valdez tanker in 1989<br />

triggered the application of Contingent valuation<br />

Methods for studies conducted in order to establish<br />

the magnitude of liability for the injuries occurred to<br />

the natural resources, under the Comprehensive,<br />

Environmental Response, Compensation and<br />

Liability Act (CERCLA). A panel headed by Nobel<br />

laureates K. Arrow and R. Solow appointed to advice<br />

NoAA on the appropriateness of use of CvM<br />

in nature resource damage assessments. In their<br />

report the panel concluded that CvM studies can<br />

produce estimates reliable enough to be the starting<br />

point of a judicial process of damage assessment<br />

including passive-use values. To apply CvM appropriately,<br />

the panel drew up a list of guidelines for<br />

contingent valuation studies. While some of the<br />

guidelines have attracted some criticism, the<br />

majority has been accepted widely.<br />

Source: Navrud and Pruckner 1996<br />

2.2.3 BROADER USES OF ECONOMIC<br />

VALUES IN POLICY-MAKING<br />

Successful biodiversity policies are often restricted to a<br />

small number of countries, because they are unknown<br />

or poorly understood beyond these countries. Economics<br />

can highlight that there are policies that<br />

already work well, deliver more benefits than costs<br />

and are effective and efficient. The REDD scheme<br />

(Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation),<br />

introduced as a key climate policy instrument in<br />

2007, has already stimulated broader interest in payment<br />

for ecosystem services (PES) (see Chapter 5). Several<br />

countries and organisations have collated case studies<br />

on REDD design and implementation that can be useful<br />

for other countries and applications (Parker et al. 2009).<br />

other examples of approaches that could be used more<br />

widely for biodiversity objectives include e.g. green<br />

public procurement and instruments based on the<br />

polluter-pays principle (see Chapter 7).<br />

<strong>TEEB</strong> foR NATIoNAL AND INTERNATIoNAL PoLICy MAKERS - ChAPTER 2: PAGE 9

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!