05.06.2013 Views

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

10.3.4 RESTORATION OF DEGRADED<br />

ECOSYSTEMS<br />

Avoiding ecosystem loss in the first place is obviously<br />

the better option, but where it is already too late,<br />

well-targeted restoration of natural capital can<br />

provide very high returns on investment in<br />

certain contexts. Preliminary estimates presented in<br />

the <strong>TEEB</strong> Climate Issues Update (2009) suggested<br />

that the potential social returns of return can reach<br />

40% for mangrove and woodland/shrublands,<br />

50% for tropical forests and 79% for grasslands when<br />

the multiple ecosystem services provided are taken<br />

into account.<br />

Despite the promising potential for high returns,<br />

ecological infrastructure projects require significant<br />

up-front investment. The costs vary widely, not only<br />

RESPONDING TO THE VALUE OF NATURE<br />

Figure 10.2: Total benefits of conservation compared to benefits from conversion for<br />

seven case studies in different countries<br />

Sources: Bann (1997), Yaron (2001), van Vuuren and Roy (1993), van Beukering et al. (2003), Kumari (1994), Naidoo and Ricketts (2006),<br />

and White et al. (2000), as reviewed by Balmford et al. (2002), Papageorgiou (2008) and Trivedi et al. (2008). ‘Conservation’<br />

includes sustainable production of market goods and services including timber, fish, non-timber forest products, and tourism.<br />

‘Conversion’ refers to replacement of the natural ecosystem with a system dedicated to agriculture, aquaculture, or timber production.<br />

between ecosystem types but also according to the<br />

level of degradation, the level of ambition and the<br />

specific circumstances in which restoration is carried<br />

out. Evidence on costs collected in this report range<br />

from hundreds to thousands of Euros per hectare in<br />

grasslands, rangelands and forests, to several tens of<br />

thousands in inland waters, and even up to millions of<br />

dollars per hectare for coral reefs (see Chapter 9).<br />

Another constraint is that the expected benefits, even<br />

when they are marketable (such as in the case of<br />

freshwater provision or waste treatment) can take time<br />

to materialise. Together with the high costs, this can<br />

put off private investment, meaning that the role of<br />

governments and public budgets is critical.<br />

Government support and coordination of stakeholders<br />

is particularly important for mega-sites of degradation<br />

with large-scale complex interactions and far-reaching<br />

<strong>TEEB</strong> FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 10: PAGE 18

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!