05.06.2013 Views

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The multiple policy objectives often associated with<br />

subsidy programmes need to be analysed carefully.<br />

Disentangling explicit and implicit objectives can help<br />

identify opportunities to introduce separate, better<br />

designed and more transparent instruments. During<br />

a recent reform of forestry subsidies in Finland, for<br />

example, a specific Forest Biodiversity Programme<br />

was created which provides regular payments for<br />

landowners in return for maintaining or improving<br />

specified biodiversity values of the forest. By separately<br />

targeting the biodiversity objective, the programme is<br />

more transparent, and its cost-effectiveness easier to<br />

assess, than general forestry subsidies with several<br />

objectives (OECD 2007a).<br />

Information from analytical frameworks (e.g. the<br />

OECD’s integrated assessment) can only build the<br />

case for reform if it is understandable by the general<br />

public and widely disseminated. Increased transparency<br />

is a major factor in the push to reform environmentally<br />

harmful subsidies (see Box 6.15 on EU<br />

transparency policy and Box 6.16 on German coal<br />

subsidy reform). Transparency is a key precondition<br />

for well-informed public debate on current subsidy<br />

programmes and can also make subsidy reform more<br />

appealing. Identifying who benefits from subsidies and<br />

highlighting their relative bargaining power can provide<br />

a powerful motivating force for change (OECD 2003a).<br />

Governments need to build alliances for change and<br />

discourage behaviour that would reduce or distort<br />

change. Reform practitioners regularly underline<br />

Box 6.16: Public support to coal mining<br />

in Germany<br />

Direct subsidies to coal have been a major issue<br />

in Germany. A 1994 decision of the German<br />

Constitutional Court ruled that previous industry<br />

subsidy – a surcharge on the price of electricity –<br />

was unconstitutional. This led to the subsidy being<br />

paid directly from the state budget which made its<br />

cost to the economy clearer and contributed to<br />

pressure for reform. Subsidies were reduced from<br />

€ 4.7 billion in 1998 to € 2.7 billion in 2005 and<br />

will be phased out completely by 2018.<br />

Source: IEEP et al. 2007<br />

REFORMING SUBSIDIES<br />

stakeholder engagement as another key precondition<br />

for durable reform. Multi-stakeholder processes<br />

based on a deliberate outreach and communications<br />

strategy can help to reach consensus – or at least<br />

common understanding – on new approaches or<br />

options for reform. The overarching goal is less about<br />

convincing stakeholders who gain most from the status<br />

quo and more about using the planning and implementation<br />

process to minimise opposition to change and<br />

maximise forces in favour of it (OECD 2003a).<br />

There is also a critical need to establish a process to<br />

build cooperation and horizontal analysis between<br />

government departments and agencies whose<br />

mandates, policies and programmes may overlap<br />

within the subsidised sectors. Subsidy reform often<br />

requires a ‘whole-government approach’ linking<br />

relevant institutional actors to ensure policy coherence<br />

(OECD 2003a).<br />

Changes in the policy landscape can open windows<br />

of opportunity (see also Chapter 2), even if sweeping<br />

electoral victories of parties with a strong reform<br />

agenda are rare. Even in such cases, practitioners<br />

caution against jumping straight to the ‘best’ solution,<br />

for several reasons, including the limited capacity of<br />

governments to undertake major reforms on many<br />

fronts at the same time; and the limited capacity for<br />

short-term adaptation by affected communities. In<br />

practice, demonstrating actual benefits delivered<br />

through more gradual reforms can be more compelling<br />

than up-front projections of expected benefits (even if<br />

these are larger). For the same reasons, dramatic<br />

reforms may also increase the likelihood of policy<br />

reversal (OECD 2005).<br />

Having said this, cases of fast and successful reform<br />

do exist (see Boxes 6.12, 6.13 and 6.17). Despite the<br />

earlier words of caution, a key advantage of eliminating<br />

or changing subsidies immediately, without prior<br />

warning, is that recipients cannot take advantage of<br />

the phase-out period to increase their entitlements,<br />

thus leading to associated environmental damage.<br />

<strong>TEEB</strong> FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 6: PAGE 30

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!