05.06.2013 Views

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

could have adverse consequences for biodiversity if<br />

deforestation/degradation were displaced from an area<br />

with low biodiversity value to one with higher value. In<br />

general, national level emissions accounting is better<br />

able to account for international leakage than sub-national<br />

and/or project level accounting 11 .<br />

Another important question about REDD relates to<br />

‘additionality’ i.e. achieving emission reductions<br />

that are additional to what would have occurred<br />

under the business-as-usual scenario and how<br />

protected areas (PAs) are treated within this context.<br />

Some high carbon/high biodiversity ecosystems may<br />

be located in legally-defined PAs, giving the impression<br />

that the carbon they store is safe and that they<br />

would not offer additional sequestration benefits.<br />

While this is true for well-managed PAs, many sites<br />

remain vulnerable to degradation through encroachment,<br />

poaching and other illegal activities (Leverington<br />

et al. 2008). This reflects inter alia the significant<br />

financing gap that exists for many PAs across the<br />

world (see Chapter 8).<br />

Ensuring carbon additionality will depend on whether<br />

and how REDD finance is extended to PAs. About<br />

312 Gt of terrestrial carbon is currently stored in the<br />

existing PA network: if lost to the atmosphere, this<br />

would be equivalent to approximately 23 times the<br />

total global anthropogenic carbon emissions for 2004<br />

(Kapos et al. 2008). Targeting REDD funding at PAs<br />

at risk of degradation/deforestation or which have potential<br />

for improved ecological status – rather than at<br />

‘safe’ PAs – could yield both high carbon and biodiversity<br />

benefits.<br />

GROSS VS NET DEFORESTATION RATES<br />

REWARDING BENEFITS THROUGH PAYMENTS AND MARKETS<br />

Another issue under negotiation is whether gross<br />

or net deforestation rates will be considered when estimating<br />

emission reductions 12 . From a climate perspective,<br />

the most relevant figure is what the<br />

atmosphere actually experiences (the rationale for using<br />

net values). However, the use of net rates could hide<br />

the loss of mature (i.e. primary and modified natural)<br />

forests and their replacement with areas of new forest,<br />

either in situ or elsewhere. This could result in significant<br />

losses in biodiversity (sCBD 2008).<br />

REDD FINANCING<br />

There are three prevailing positions on how REDD<br />

financing could be generated 13 . These have different<br />

implications for how biodiversity co-benefits could be<br />

promoted and which stakeholders would be involved<br />

in decision-making processes.<br />

Market-based approaches: If REDD were financed<br />

via the regulated international carbon market, credits<br />

would need to be fungible (interchangeable) with existing<br />

Assigned Amount Units (AAUs) under the Kyoto<br />

market 14 . The unit of exchange would be tonnes of<br />

carbon equivalents (tCO 2 e). Demand for credits would<br />

be generated by the carbon market which would drive<br />

investment towards the least-cost mitigation options<br />

(subject to any restrictions that governments might<br />

place on market access for REDD credits). Given their<br />

ability to engage the private sector, market-based<br />

approaches to REDD are likely to mobilise higher levels<br />

of sustainable and long-term financing, leading to<br />

larger areas of conserved forests and larger biodiversity<br />

co-benefits.<br />

Fund-based approaches: Another approach is to<br />

mobilise REDD finance via inter alia voluntary contributions<br />

(ODA), auctioning assigned amount units<br />

(AAUs) in the carbon market and earmarking (part of)<br />

these revenues or revenues from other fees, fines and<br />

taxes. In general, fund-based approaches can be designed<br />

to disburse REDD finance based on any objectives<br />

and criteria established by donor (and host)<br />

countries. Whereas carbon market financing is tied<br />

to delivering emission reductions, fund-based approaches<br />

could be used not only to finance such reductions<br />

but also to support capacity-building needs<br />

in developing countries to make REDD operational.<br />

They may also target biodiversity co-benefits or<br />

be designed to target biodiversity benefits directly.<br />

However, the way in which funds are generated may<br />

have implications for how they are disbursed (see Karousakis<br />

2009). In general, fund-based approaches<br />

are likely to deliver lower volumes of REDD finance<br />

over the long-run.<br />

Phased approaches: More recently, a phased<br />

approach to REDD finance has been proposed that<br />

combines market and fund-based approaches. The<br />

<strong>TEEB</strong> FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 5: PAGE 26

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!