Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

05.06.2013 Views

REWARDING BENEFITS THROUGH PAYMENTS AND MARKETS imposing management obligations. Other beneficiaries of ecosystem services may find that the reference level of service provision does not meet their needs and therefore make voluntary payments to resource owners. In some cases, governments may chose to use PES pragmatically as an incentive to get practice up to the legal standard – here it operates simply as a subsidy (see also Chapter 6) and runs counter to the ‘polluter pays principle’ (PPP). This cannot really be seen as a long-term solution, given concerns related to cost, budgets, governance, equity and efficiency. In other cases, governments may find it more appropriate to raise standards, strengthen enforcement and implement the PPP more fully (see Chapter 7). It should be noted that even with legal standards complemented by positive incentives, there will often be some residual adverse environmental impacts compared with undisturbed ecosystems. These impacts are ultimately borne by society unless or until cost-effective means or technological solutions are found to avoid them. For example, pesticide or fertiliser use may comply with standards and even respond to incentive instruments designed either to discourage their use (e.g. taxes and charges, see Chapter 7) or to reward reductions in use (PES). Despite this, impacts may remain to the extent that relevant legislation and targets do not demand zero impact i.e. where use of fertilisers or pesticides is within the assimilative or regenerative capacity of the ecosystem (see Figure 5.3). For these reasons, the effectiveness and feasibility of PES is closely tied to the regulatory baseline and its enforcement (see Chapter 7). A key challenge is to determine the appropriate reference level i.e. to distinguish between what resource owners/managers can reasonably be expected to do at their own cost and what more they might agree to undertake on the basis of PES. The answer will depend on how environmental rights and duties are allocated between beneficiaries and Figure 5.3: PES and the Polluter Pays Principle (PPP) Source: Patrick ten Brink, own representation building on Scheele 2008 TEEB FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 5: PAGE 9

REWARDING BENEFITS THROUGH PAYMENTS AND MARKETS providers, whether formally or through de facto established practices. This varies between different legal systems and social contexts. Where downstream populations assert a right to clean water, it may be considered that upstream landowners should bear the costs of reducing pollution in accordance with the polluter pays principle. Conversely, if those landowners enjoy unencumbered rights to manage their land as they see fit, the burden of persuading them to modify their practices may fall on service beneficiaries (Johnstone and Bishop 2007) 4 . PES are sometimes criticised as a ‘second best’ solution by those who believe that beneficiaries have a right to enjoy ecosystem services that would have been available in the absence of damaging activities (i.e. free public goods delivered by nature); based on this argument, PES is less ethically satisfactory than strengthening the law to make polluters pay. Others suggest that PES is often just a disguised subsidy to encourage compliance with existing laws and can unfairly burden the public purse (where governments finance PES). In response to such concerns, the justification for PES is that it can be more cost-effective than strict enforcement, more progressive (where providers are relatively poor land users), and/or that it secures additional bene- fits beyond the minimum legal requirements. PES can also be seen as a temporary measure to motivate the adoption of new management practices and technologies which may eventually become economically justifiable in their own right (Johnstone, N. and Bishop, J. 2007). Defining reference levels in terms of business-as-usual scenarios (BAU) carries a risk that resource owners exaggerate the level of environmental threat in order to win more payments for conservation 5 . This risk is particularly relevant in the case of REDD (e.g. overstating the rate of deforestation that would occur in a BAU scenario without payments: see Section 5.2 below). THE STRUCTURE OF PES Figure 5.4: PES stakeholders and their interactions As noted in Section 5.1.1, PES are highly flexible and there is no one model or blueprint. There are many ways to structure schemes, depending on the specific service, scale of application and context for implementation. Some are based on legal obligations (e.g. PES linked to carbon markets under legally-binding emission targets) whereas private PES schemes are voluntary with little government TEEB FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 5: PAGE 10 Source: adapted from Pagiola 2003

REWARDING BENEFITS THROUGH PAYMENTS AND MARKETS<br />

imposing management obligations. Other beneficiaries<br />

of ecosystem services may find that the reference level<br />

of service provision does not meet their needs and therefore<br />

make voluntary payments to resource owners.<br />

In some cases, governments may chose to use PES<br />

pragmatically as an incentive to get practice up to<br />

the legal standard – here it operates simply as a subsidy<br />

(see also Chapter 6) and runs counter to the<br />

‘polluter pays principle’ (PPP). This cannot really be<br />

seen as a long-term solution, given concerns related<br />

to cost, budgets, governance, equity and efficiency.<br />

In other cases, governments may find it more appropriate<br />

to raise standards, strengthen enforcement<br />

and implement the PPP more fully (see Chapter 7).<br />

It should be noted that even with legal standards<br />

complemented by positive incentives, there will often<br />

be some residual adverse environmental impacts<br />

compared with undisturbed ecosystems. These impacts<br />

are ultimately borne by society unless or until<br />

cost-effective means or technological solutions are<br />

found to avoid them. For example, pesticide or<br />

fertiliser use may comply with standards and even<br />

respond to incentive instruments designed either to<br />

discourage their use (e.g. taxes and charges, see<br />

Chapter 7) or to reward reductions in use (PES).<br />

Despite this, impacts may remain to the extent that<br />

relevant legislation and targets do not demand zero<br />

impact i.e. where use of fertilisers or pesticides is<br />

within the assimilative or regenerative capacity of the<br />

ecosystem (see Figure 5.3).<br />

For these reasons, the effectiveness and feasibility<br />

of PES is closely tied to the regulatory baseline<br />

and its enforcement (see Chapter 7). A key<br />

challenge is to determine the appropriate reference<br />

level i.e. to distinguish between what resource<br />

owners/managers can reasonably be expected to do<br />

at their own cost and what more they might agree<br />

to undertake on the basis of PES.<br />

The answer will depend on how environmental rights<br />

and duties are allocated between beneficiaries and<br />

Figure 5.3: PES and the Polluter Pays Principle (PPP)<br />

Source: Patrick ten Brink, own representation building on Scheele 2008<br />

<strong>TEEB</strong> FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 5: PAGE 9

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!