05.06.2013 Views

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

Download (PDF, 6.71MB) - TEEB

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

REWARDING BENEFITS THROUGH PAYMENTS AND MARKETS<br />

national governments, as in Costa Rica, Ecuador, Mexico,<br />

China, EU Member States and the US. Others are<br />

established by water companies or water-user associations,<br />

as in the Catskills where PES is used to meet<br />

federal water quality standards for New York City and<br />

in Bolivia, Ecuador and Mexico. PES can also be purely<br />

private arrangements, whereby companies that rely on<br />

specific ecosystem services pay the relevant providers<br />

(e.g. payments to farmers by Perrier-Vittel in France:<br />

see Box 5.4). NGOs can also play an important role in<br />

PES e.g. by collaborating with the municipal water<br />

company in Quito (Wunder et al. 2009).<br />

PES can be applied at different scales, ranging from<br />

the very local (e.g. 496 hectares in an upper watershed<br />

in northern Ecuador) to much larger scales (e.g. 4.9<br />

million hectares of sloping farmland reforested in China<br />

(Bennett 2008; see also Chapter 9).<br />

5.1.2 PRINCIPLES AND ARCHITECTURE<br />

OF PES<br />

RATIONALE FOR INVESTING IN PES<br />

The overarching principle of PES is to ensure that people<br />

who benefit from a particular ecosystem service compensate<br />

those who provide the service, giving the latter<br />

group an incentive to continue doing so (see Figure 5.1).<br />

As noted, policy makers are not the only ones concerned.<br />

Other beneficiaries of ecosystem services – such<br />

as hydroelectric power companies, irrigation authorities,<br />

water companies or aquaculture operations – may also<br />

be willing to pay to secure services that underpin their<br />

businesses. Private beneficiaries who make PES contracts<br />

with providers can thus internalise (some) environmental<br />

externalities on a purely voluntary basis.<br />

PES are intended to change the economics of ecosystem<br />

management and can support biodiversity-friendly<br />

practices that benefit society as a<br />

whole (see Figure 5.2). In a situation where trade-offs<br />

exist between private and societal benefits from land<br />

uses, PES can tip the balance and render conservationfocused<br />

land uses more privately profitable with benefits<br />

for both the private land user and for society. In the<br />

absence of PES, the landowner would not choose the<br />

social optimum – unless other instruments such as regulation<br />

or incentives are in place (e.g. tax concessions,<br />

see Section 5.4) or social and cultural norms, customs<br />

or considerations lead to a social optimum without the<br />

need for payment. Care is needed to ensure that the instrument<br />

is socially compatible.<br />

Care is also needed in their design as not all PES<br />

protect or conserve biodiversity. A focus on maximising<br />

the provision of just one service may have negative impacts<br />

on the provision of other ecosystem services if<br />

trade-offs are involved e.g. PES that promote exotic<br />

species plantations for rapid carbon sequestration at<br />

the expense of more diverse natural grasslands, which<br />

foster higher biodiversity.<br />

Figure 5.1: Funding the provision of ecosystem services<br />

Source: Patrick ten Brink, own representation<br />

<strong>TEEB</strong> FOR NATIONAL AND INTERNATIONAL POLICY MAKERS - CHAPTER 5: PAGE 7

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!