28.05.2013 Views

Etude des marchés d'assurance non-vie à l'aide d'équilibres de ...

Etude des marchés d'assurance non-vie à l'aide d'équilibres de ...

Etude des marchés d'assurance non-vie à l'aide d'équilibres de ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

tel-00703797, version 2 - 7 Jun 2012<br />

Chapitre 2. Theorie <strong><strong>de</strong>s</strong> jeux et cycles <strong>de</strong> marché<br />

since strategic environments (action sets) evolve over a time, the action set is not finite and<br />

stochastic pertubations complete the picture.<br />

We choose a repeated game but with infinite action space, such that at each period,<br />

insurers set new premiums <strong>de</strong>pending on past observed losses. A generalized Nash equilibrium<br />

is computed at each period. Our repeated game does not enter the framework of dynamic<br />

games as presented in Basar and Ols<strong>de</strong>r (1999), but it shares some properties of Markov games<br />

and classical repeated games.<br />

2.4.2 Deriving a dynamic mo<strong>de</strong>l<br />

In this subsection, we <strong><strong>de</strong>s</strong>cribe the repeated game framework. Now, insurers have a past<br />

history: past premium x ⋆ j,t gross written premium GWPj,t, portfolio size nj,t, capital Kj,t at<br />

the beginning of year t. Let d be the history <strong>de</strong>pth for which economic variables (e.g. market<br />

premium) will be computed. In this setting, objective Oj,t and constraint functions gj,t are<br />

also time-<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt.<br />

At the beginning of each time period, the average market premium is <strong>de</strong>termined as<br />

¯mt−1 = 1<br />

d<br />

d<br />

u=1<br />

N j=1 GWPj,t−u × x⋆ j,t−u<br />

<br />

GWP.,t−u<br />

<br />

,<br />

<br />

market premium for year t−u<br />

which is the mean of last d market premiums. With current portfolio size nj,t−1 and initial<br />

capital Kj,t−1, each insurer computes its actuarially based premium as<br />

1 1<br />

āj,t =<br />

1 − ej,t d<br />

d sj,t−u<br />

nj,t−u<br />

<br />

,<br />

avg ind loss<br />

where sj,t <strong>de</strong>notes the observed aggregate loss of insurer j during year t. Thus, break-even<br />

premiums are πj,t = ωjāj,t + (1 − ωj) ¯mt−1. Thus, the objective function in the dynamic mo<strong>de</strong>l<br />

is given by<br />

Oj,t(x) = nj,t<br />

n<br />

and the solvency constraint function by<br />

u=1<br />

<br />

xj<br />

1 − βj,t − 1 (xj − πj,t) ,<br />

mj(x)<br />

g 1 j,t(xj) = Kj,t + nj,t(xj − πj,t)(1 − ej,t)<br />

k995σ(Y ) √ nj,t<br />

It is important to note that the characteristics of insurers evolve over time, notably the breakeven<br />

premium πj,t, the expense rate ej,t and the sentivity parameter βj,t.<br />

The game sequence for period t is as follows<br />

116<br />

1. The insurers maximize their objective function subject to the solvency constraint<br />

sup<br />

xj,t<br />

− 1.<br />

Oj,t(xj,t, x−j,t) such that gj,t(xj,t) ≥ 0.<br />

2. Once the premium equilibrium vector x ⋆ t is <strong>de</strong>termined, customers randomly lapse or<br />

renew, so we get a realization n ⋆ j,t of the random variable Nj,t(x ⋆ ).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!