28.05.2013 Views

Etude des marchés d'assurance non-vie à l'aide d'équilibres de ...

Etude des marchés d'assurance non-vie à l'aide d'équilibres de ...

Etude des marchés d'assurance non-vie à l'aide d'équilibres de ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

tel-00703797, version 2 - 7 Jun 2012<br />

Chapitre 2. Theorie <strong><strong>de</strong>s</strong> jeux et cycles <strong>de</strong> marché<br />

2.1 Introduction<br />

Insurance market cycles and the study of their causes have been puzzling actuaries for<br />

many years. Feldblum (2001) discusses four main causes that could explain the presence of<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rwriting through their aggregate effect. These causes are (i) actuarial pricing procedure,<br />

(ii) un<strong>de</strong>rwriting philosophy, (iii) interest rate fluctuations and (iv) competitive strategies. He<br />

compares contributions through out the 20 th century on the topic, see also Markham (2007)<br />

for an over<strong>vie</strong>w.<br />

Actuarial pricing procedures are subject to claim cost uncertainty, information lag (due<br />

to accouting, regulatory and legal standards). Such effects are likely to generate fluctuations<br />

around an equilibrium price, when extrapolating premiums, see, e.g., Venezian (1985); Cummins<br />

and Outreville (1987). In addition, a hard behavior of un<strong>de</strong>rwriters combined with a<br />

lack of coordination is an extra recipe for un<strong>de</strong>rwriting cycles. In particular, price policies<br />

cannot be sold in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>ntly of the market premium, but neither can the market premium be<br />

driven by one’s individual actions. This is called un<strong>de</strong>rwriting philosophy by Feldblum (2001),<br />

and is also noticed in Jablonowski (1985), who assumes (i) insurers do not make <strong>de</strong>cisions in<br />

isolation from other firms in the market, and (ii) profit maximization is not the exclusive,<br />

or even the most important, motivation of insurers. Interest rate <strong>de</strong>viations further increase<br />

the frequency and the amplitu<strong>de</strong> of market cycles, as they have an impact on the investment<br />

result and (indirectly) on the maximum rebate that un<strong>de</strong>rwriters can afford to keep presumably<br />

low-risk customers. Fields and Venezian (1989) were among the first to <strong>de</strong>monstrate this<br />

effect. Finally, the competition level on most mature insurance markets are such that any<br />

increase in market share can only be carried out by price <strong>de</strong>crease ∗ (due to very little product<br />

differentiation). Coupled with capital constraints (e.g. Gron (1994)) and price inelasticity,<br />

insurers are forced not to <strong>de</strong>viate too much from market trends.<br />

On a different level, basic economic mo<strong>de</strong>ls suggest that the equilibrium premium is the<br />

marginal cost, as any upward <strong>de</strong>viation from this equilibrium will result in losing all the policies<br />

in the next period. This theory would imply that all insurers price at the market premium<br />

However, in practice customers do not move from a insurer to a cheaper insurer as swiftly<br />

as economic mo<strong>de</strong>ls anticipate. There is an inertia of the insurance <strong>de</strong>mand, preventing all<br />

insured to shop arround for the cheapest insurer when their premium is slightly higher than the<br />

market premium. So customer behavior is much more complicated. In addition to customer<br />

loyalty, Feldblum (2001) points out that it is difficult for a new insurer to enter successfully<br />

into the <strong>non</strong>-life insurance market.<br />

More refined economic mo<strong>de</strong>ls focus on moral hazard and adverse selection. The celebrated<br />

mo<strong>de</strong>l of Rothschild and Stiglitz (see Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976)) <strong>de</strong>als with a utility-based<br />

agent framework where insureds have private information on their own risk. Insurers provi<strong>de</strong><br />

a menu of contracts (a pair of premium and <strong>de</strong>ductible) and high-risk individuals choose<br />

full coverage, whereas low-risk individuals are more attracted by partial coverage. Note that<br />

the equilibrium price may not exist if all insurers offer just one type of contract. Picard<br />

(2009) consi<strong>de</strong>rs an extension by allowing insurers to offer participating contracts (such as<br />

mutual-type contracts). This feature guarantees the existence of an equilibrium, which forces<br />

(rational) insureds to reveal their risk level. An important source of applications of such<br />

mo<strong>de</strong>ls is health insurance where moral hazard and adverse selection play a major role, see,<br />

∗. The hunger for market share is driven by the resulting reduction of claim uncertainty is increasing the<br />

policy number, which is motivated by the law of large numbers.<br />

94

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!