10.04.2013 Views

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Conover Bribery in Classical Athens Chapter One<br />

associated with bribery, transacting in bribes—i.e. violating social norms—requires an<br />

enormous amount of trust. Typically, high-risk transactions are conducted through<br />

previously existing social relations, as the social relations themselves act to diffuse the<br />

risk associated with the transaction. 11 Where there are no previous social relations to<br />

guide transactors, local norms can guarantee the security of the transaction: where bribes<br />

are expected, there is little risk that they will be punished. 12 The majority of bribe<br />

transactions is thus conducted between actors who are either already linked through some<br />

social network or who can rely on prevailing institutional norms to know that the<br />

transaction is safe. This confines the giving and taking of bribes predominantly to well-<br />

defined networks of actors; people are either ‘in’ the network, or they are ‘out’ of it. 13<br />

Conflicting social frames arise when ‘insiders’ view the actions in terms of one<br />

frame, ‘outsiders’ another. On the one hand, bribe-giver and bribe-taker (the insiders)<br />

regularly frame the bribe and the service for which it is purportedly exchanged as distinct<br />

media for negotiating, contesting, and constituting a local relationship amongst<br />

themselves. As such, bribe and service can readily be framed as reciprocal gifts, not as<br />

quid pro quo compensation 14 ; often, too, they are understood as part of a longer sequence<br />

11<br />

DiMaggio and Louch (1998), and, on bribery, Humphrey (1991), Ledeneva (1998, 2008), Lambsdorff<br />

(2002), Uslaner (2004), Pardo (2004b).<br />

12<br />

Graeff (2005).<br />

13<br />

Pardo (2004b)’s study of Italian corruption demonstrates this point well in illustrating how low-level<br />

corruption requiring relatively little trust was conducted among individuals outside of any network whereas<br />

high-level corruption, requiring much higher levels of trust, was conducted via networks. Of course, in the<br />

case of prevailing local norms, simply entering into the correct institutional context—e.g. interacting with<br />

the appropriate governmental office, widely known to demand bribes—can be all it takes to become an<br />

‘insider’: see further Humphrey (1991) on outsider distinctions involving bribery. Ledeneva (1998: 39-<br />

42) differentiates bribery from blat (personal influence) by the presence or absence of networks, but she<br />

takes too narrow an understanding of bribery as entailing the use of money (qua cash). Instead, I would<br />

point out that the currency of blat networks can appear to be bribes to outsiders. In this sense, blat and<br />

bribery on Ledeneva’s definition are gradations of a range of collaborative activity that can be termed<br />

‘bribery’ on my definition.<br />

14<br />

Indeed, when there is frequent reciprocal giving within a relationship, the particular ‘bribe’ and service<br />

may be thought by insiders as completely unrelated to each other. Note how the reverse is usually the case<br />

34

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!