10.04.2013 Views

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Conover Bribery in Classical Athens Conclusion<br />

The view from Athens suggests that these questions are perhaps the wrong ones to<br />

ask. For the Athenians, bribery was not a discrete problem that could simply be solved<br />

(or reduced to a minimal equilibrium); rather, it was a mode of politics that, along with<br />

the democracy, changed, reinvented itself, took on new meaning, and thus had to be<br />

constantly re-incorporated into the workings of the democracy. Athenian bribery, like the<br />

democracy itself, was not a static phenomenon—some isolated inefficiency in the<br />

workings of polity—but was ever dynamic. In other words, precisely because the<br />

democracy was always changing, there was never any set equilibrium for which the<br />

Athenians were striving: certainly Plato and Aristotle understood that polities were<br />

always in motion, always evolving or devolving over time. As a result, there was never<br />

any static ideal of ‘good government’ against which bribery could be measured. To<br />

speak of ‘more’ or ‘less’ bribery at Athens would be to miss the point that the Athenians<br />

seemed okay with even a considerable amount of bribery, provided it could be leveraged<br />

in some way for the good of the democracy.<br />

It is important, in this regard, to underscore the very different way in which the<br />

Athenians approached the concept of bribery. For them the normative value of dōra did<br />

not depend on the context in which they were given or received (e.g. public office), or<br />

even the intent with which they were given. It hinged, instead, on the perceived result of<br />

costs in time, money, and effort: e.g. Klitgaard (1988: 24). What conventional political economic wisdom<br />

suggests is that the ideal amount of bribery lies at the equilibrium where trying to regulate it further would<br />

accrue more costs than simply letting the bribery exist. It could be argued that, given severe informational<br />

asymmetries in the world of Athenian politics—that is, given the enormous costs of trying to monitor<br />

public officials’ financial accounts—this equilibrium was astonishingly high at Athens; on this view, given<br />

Athens’ inefficient technologies for monitoring public officials, we could only expect that they would have<br />

a high amount of bribery.<br />

This view is unattractive, however, given the extreme monitoring the Athenians actually achieved:<br />

they employed treasurers whose sole job was to look after the accounts of generals, they examined the<br />

financial accounts of magistrates ten times a year, and the Athenians did not seem shy about bringing a<br />

bribery suit against an official. Indeed, if political economists have correctly modeled the cost-benefit<br />

analysis of bribery and its regulation, then Athens’ success as democracy and economy is doubly<br />

impressive, for she invested seemingly excessive resources in combating corruption.<br />

325

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!