10.04.2013 Views

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Conover Bribery in Classical Athens Chapter Four<br />

constitutional change were well on their way. Not just another isolated Timagoras,<br />

Aeschines was emblematic of a larger class of ponēroi, lying rogues bought by Philip at<br />

the price of the city’s destruction and plotting the city’s demise from within (Dem.<br />

19.68). Accordingly, Demosthenes recommends that Aeschines be punished to serve as a<br />

lesson to all the current and would-be traitors in Athens (Dem. 19.231-2, 339-40, 343).<br />

Although we should be wary of taking any orator at his word, there appears to<br />

have been at least some truth to Demosthenes’ picture of stasis and pervasive distrust. 25<br />

Indeed, after the conclusion of the Social War in 355—and only two years after Philip<br />

had taken Pydna and Amphipolis—amid considerable anxieties over financial recovery,<br />

Athens was especially vulnerable to the threat of stasis. For one, Philip’s imposing<br />

presence in the Aegean was a direct threat to Athens’ interests in securing grain from<br />

Thrace. 26 As a result, Athens’ use of a select few citizens to handle relations with the<br />

Spartacid Kings in Thrace—and thereby to secure favorable trade terms—became a risky<br />

endeavor, it was thought, for those few elites might easily be corrupted by the enemy to<br />

divert the grain elsewhere. 27 What is more, the Social War and, with it, the demise of the<br />

25<br />

As Plato’s intense focus on stasis would suggest. So, for instance, Rep. 4.422e-423a remarks, “Any<br />

state, however small, is in fact divided into two, one the state of the poor, the other the state of the rich.”<br />

On fourth-century Athenians’ preoccupation with stasis, see further Fuks (1972, 1977, 1979), de Ste. Croix<br />

(1981: 69-80), Brock (2000: 27-30), Kalimtzis (2000: 15-31). Similarly, Aeneas Tacticus’ manual on<br />

siegecraft (350’s) is rife with concerns that the polis might be attacked by its own citizens: e.g. Aen. Tact.<br />

10.20, 14.1, 17.1, 22.21. Cf. Whitehead (1990: 25-33). Note how when the League of Corinth was formed<br />

in 337, there was a clause explicitly aimed at preventing constitutional subversion: Tod 177.12-14; cf.<br />

[Dem.] 17.5, 12, 15.<br />

26<br />

See Oliver (2007: 43-4) on the successful threat Philip posed to Athen’s ability to police maritime trade<br />

in the 340’s and 330’s.<br />

27<br />

Beginning in the late fifth and early fourth centuries, ties between the Spartacids and traders in the<br />

Bosporan region were notoriously close: traders were given tax breaks and priority in loading their cargo<br />

(Dem. 20.31-2), as well as ateleia at the emporion at Theodosia (Dem. 20.33); Bosporan elites were<br />

educated at Athenian schools (Isoc. 17.4, 15.224); and Athenian elites regularly spoke in favor of awarding<br />

Bosporan elites statues and public honors (Gauthier [1985: 156-7]; Oliver [2007: 23]). Moreno (2007:<br />

175-9) provides an exhaustive treatment. Concerns about corruption and the grain trade were thus<br />

pronounced—Lysias 22 is a classic early example of fears in this area—but ultimately these did not include<br />

fears of treason. Whereas the grain-dealers in Lysias 22 might be castigated for trying to harm the dēmos<br />

(Lys. 22.14-15) and even for colluding to get rich (Lys. 22.20), they were not suspected of trying to<br />

180

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!