10.04.2013 Views

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

BRIBERY IN CLASSICAL ATHENS Kellam ... - Historia Antigua

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Conover Bribery in Classical Athens Chapter Two<br />

monies were used instead. 55 As Plutarch records, rather than allow Pericles to put his<br />

name on the building (in return for funding it), the Athenians competed with him for the<br />

honor and spared no expense in the “liturgy” (xorhgei=n) they collectively performed. 56<br />

Individual expenditure on public works all but vanishes from our record after this time.<br />

In keeping distinct the monies of patronage and empire, the dēmos thereby<br />

underscored how problematic their overlap—represented, above, by the dōrodokos—<br />

could be. What, though, was so problematic about their overlap? We can perhaps find<br />

an answer in reversing the direction of an analogy Plutarch makes between liturgies and<br />

the dēmos’ outlay of imperial monies. If the dēmos’ outlay of imperial monies (public<br />

works symbolic of Athenian archē) was analogous to an elite patron’s benefactions to the<br />

city, then were not a patron’s benefactions steeped in the same symbolism as the monies<br />

of empire? So long as the boundaries between the two economies remained porous, so<br />

long as the same monies could be used to negotiate both economies simultaneously,<br />

Athens’ recent shift to empire could be refracted through the monies used to negotiate the<br />

relationship between an elite citizen and the community. 57 Patrons of the community<br />

could fast become imperial masters of the dēmos.<br />

In fact, this exact discursive shift seems to have occurred, and we can track it,<br />

again, by looking at the dōrodokos. I suggest that, as Athens’ imperial archē became<br />

55 3<br />

IG i 49.13-14 (430’s BCE); cf. Plut. Per. 14.1-2. For background and discussion, see Stadter (1989:<br />

181-2 ad Per. 14.1), Kallet (1998: 48), Domingo Gygax (forthcoming: 206-7).<br />

56<br />

Plut. Per. 14.1-2. Plutarch’s use of the language of liturgies—cf. pro\j th\n do/can a)ntifilotimou/menoi<br />

tw=n e1rgwn…xorh/gein—is telling.<br />

57<br />

Chapter Six traces another reason for why the blurring of these two economies could be so problematic:<br />

precisely because the dēmos was increasingly concerned to exact a certain amount of tribute each year,<br />

there were greater fears that individuals involved in tribute collection might somehow tamper with the<br />

funds. See, for example, IG i³ 34=ML 46.35-7, IG i 3 71.36-7. By more clearly separating public monies<br />

from the economy of patronage, the dēmos could more readily regulate them. As a result, in the second<br />

half of the fifth century we first begin to find a greater separation between ‘public’ and ‘private’:<br />

Humphreys (1978b ).<br />

102

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!