06.04.2013 Views

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Appendix C: A Cognitive Cost Model of Heterogeneous Attentiveness<br />

How does <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes vary by income? The model we develop in this Appendix<br />

does not make a uniform prediction for all goods, but r<strong>at</strong>her highlights the factors th<strong>at</strong> determine which<br />

income group will be more <strong>at</strong>tentive for a particular good. We then consider those factors in the context<br />

of cigarettes to predict whether high- or low-income consumers are likely to be more <strong>at</strong>tentive to cigarette<br />

register taxes.<br />

Suppose all agents have the option of paying <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes, but th<strong>at</strong> doing so carries with it<br />

some positive utility cost. 36 This "cognitive cost" could stem from the mental effort needed to remember<br />

and calcul<strong>at</strong>e a good’s tax-inclusive price or might simply represent the opportunity cost of time spent on<br />

th<strong>at</strong> task.<br />

Assume th<strong>at</strong> agents’ final utility is additively separable between the cognitive cost and consumption<br />

so th<strong>at</strong> we can write Wi = U (xi,yi) − bici in which bi is a binary choice variable indic<strong>at</strong>ing whether agent<br />

i pays the congitive cost and ci is the magnitude of the cost for agent i. We assume th<strong>at</strong> the cognitive cost<br />

is fixed for a given individual in th<strong>at</strong> it does not depend on the register tax r<strong>at</strong>e (it requires just as much<br />

effort to take a 6 cent register tax into account as a 7 cent one).<br />

The timing of the model with cognitive costs proceeds as in Part I, except here we add an initial step<br />

in which agents choose whether or not they will take register taxes into account when deciding on their<br />

consumption of x. As before, all agents choose an intended consumption bundle ( ˆx, ˆy) subject to their<br />

perceived budget constraint, which we can now express as BC : xi (p + bitr +tp) + yi ≤ Mi.<br />

A few final pieces of not<strong>at</strong>ion will be helpful. Let (x∗ i ,y∗i ) denote the (optimal) bundle th<strong>at</strong> i would<br />

consume if she were to pay <strong>at</strong>tention to the register tax and let ( ˜x, ˜y) denote the (sub-optimal) bundle she<br />

would consume were she to ignore the register tax. Agents who fail to pay the cognitive cost misperceive<br />

the after-tax price of x as being lower than it actually is; as a result, they over-spend on x and under-spend<br />

on y. The net change in i’s utility from taking the tax into account is therefore given by<br />

W (x ∗ i ,y ∗ i ,1) −W ( ˜xi, ˜yi,0) = Gi − ci<br />

where Gi ≡ U (x∗ i ,y∗i ) −U ( ˜x, ˜y) represents the agent’s utility gain from consuming the optimal feasible<br />

36 The cognitive cost model we use as our starting point follows the basic approach laid out in Chetty, Looney, Kroft (2007).<br />

35

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!