Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

dataspace.princeton.edu
from dataspace.princeton.edu More from this publisher
06.04.2013 Views

[13] McDonald, John F., and Robert A. Moffitt, “The Uses of Tobit Analysis,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 62 (1980), 318–21. [14] Mullainathan, Sendhil and Eldar Shafir, “Savings Policy & Decision-Making in Low-Income Households,” In Insufficient Funds: Savings, Assets, Credit and Banking Among Low-Income Households, Michael Barr and Rebecca Blank, ed. (New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2009). [15] Orzechowski and Walker, “The Tax Burden on Tobacco,” (Arlington, Virginia: Orzechowski and Walker, 2008). [16] Slemrod, Joel and Wojciech Kopczuk, “The Optimal Elasticity of Taxable Income,” Journal of Public Economics, 84 (2002), 91-112. [17] Shue, Kelly and Erzo F. P. Luttmer, “Who Misvotes? The Effect of Differential Cognition Costs on Election Outcomes,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1 (2009), 229-257. 30

Appendix A: Welfare Analysis Under Alternate Budget Adjustment Rules Part I assumed that inattentive consumers who misperceive the price of x satisfy their budget con- straints by reducing expenditures on y. This Appendix considers the robustness of our results to alternate rules for mapping infeasible intended consumption bundles into feasible final consumption bundles. In addition to the rule that we employ, Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) identify two other “intuitive” budget adjustment rules. First, consumers who misperceive the price of x may satisfy their budget con- straints by reducing expenditures on x rather than y. This rule represents the other end of the spectrum from the one that we employ, and would be appropriate if consumers purchased x after completing their purchases of all other goods. Under this rule, it is easy to show that: ∂xB ∂tr ∂xB = ∂tp = −xB p +tr +tp ∂yB − ∂ p + xB p +tr +tp The second alternate budget adjustment considered by Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) is for inat- tentive agents to reduce consumption of both x and y to make up the income lost to the register tax. Inattentive consumers ignore the register tax when making their consumption decisions, but recognize that their net-of-tax income is lower because of the tax. For example, consumers who purchase x and y repeatedly will eventually realize that they consistently have less money in their bank account than they had anticipated. Inattentive consumers whose behavior is described by this rule will fully account for the tax’s income effect but fail to account for the tax’s substitution effect. As a result, we have: where ∂ ˜ xB ∂ p ∂xB ∂tr ∂xB ∂tp ∂xB = −xB ∂I = ∂xB ∂tr represents Hicksian (compensated) demand. As before, we consider the welfare effects of a revenue-neutral shift from posted to register taxes. 31 + ∂ ˜xB ∂ p (16) (17) (18) (19)

Appendix A: Welfare Analysis Under Altern<strong>at</strong>e Budget Adjustment Rules<br />

Part I assumed th<strong>at</strong> in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers who misperceive the price of x s<strong>at</strong>isfy their budget con-<br />

straints by reducing expenditures on y. This Appendix considers the robustness of our results to altern<strong>at</strong>e<br />

rules for mapping infeasible intended consumption bundles into feasible final consumption bundles.<br />

In addition to the rule th<strong>at</strong> we employ, Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) identify two other “intuitive”<br />

budget adjustment rules. First, consumers who misperceive the price of x may s<strong>at</strong>isfy their budget con-<br />

straints by reducing expenditures on x r<strong>at</strong>her than y. This rule represents the other end of the spectrum<br />

from the one th<strong>at</strong> we employ, and would be appropri<strong>at</strong>e if consumers purchased x after completing their<br />

purchases of all other goods. Under this rule, it is easy to show th<strong>at</strong>:<br />

∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

∂xB<br />

=<br />

∂tp<br />

= −xB<br />

p +tr +tp<br />

<br />

∂yB − ∂ p + xB<br />

p +tr +tp<br />

The second altern<strong>at</strong>e budget adjustment considered by Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) is for in<strong>at</strong>-<br />

tentive agents to reduce consumption of both x and y to make up the income lost to the register tax.<br />

In<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers ignore the register tax when making their consumption decisions, but recognize<br />

th<strong>at</strong> their net-of-tax income is lower because of the tax. For example, consumers who purchase x and y<br />

repe<strong>at</strong>edly will eventually realize th<strong>at</strong> they consistently have less money in their bank account than they<br />

had anticip<strong>at</strong>ed. In<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers whose behavior is described by this rule will fully account for the<br />

tax’s income effect but fail to account for the tax’s substitution effect. As a result, we have:<br />

where<br />

∂ ˜<br />

xB<br />

∂ p<br />

∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

∂xB<br />

∂tp<br />

∂xB<br />

= −xB<br />

∂I<br />

= ∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

represents Hicksian (compens<strong>at</strong>ed) demand.<br />

As before, we consider the welfare effects of a revenue-neutral shift from posted to register taxes.<br />

31<br />

+ ∂ ˜xB<br />

∂ p<br />

(16)<br />

(17)<br />

(18)<br />

(19)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!