06.04.2013 Views

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Substituting these conditions into (7) gives<br />

<br />

dVB <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

> 0 iff Uy (xB,yB)xB − tr<br />

tr +tp<br />

∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

γ ∂R<br />

∂tr<br />

When register taxes are zero, the distortion caused by the optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error will also be zero and<br />

hence the effect on B’s welfare will be positive. 6 When register taxes represent a large fraction of the<br />

total tax on x, a further shift in th<strong>at</strong> direction can reduce B’s welfare by exacerb<strong>at</strong>ing her optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

error. So although shifting towards a register tax always benefits <strong>at</strong>tentive consumers, the welfare effect<br />

for in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers depends on the fraction of the combined tax currently imposed <strong>at</strong> the register.<br />

For simplicity, we have assumed th<strong>at</strong> the pre-tax price of x is fixed <strong>at</strong> p. In reality, firms may adjust the<br />

price they charge for x in response to changes in the type of tax imposed. If a shift from posted to register<br />

taxes induced firms to raise p by a sufficient quantity, the policy could end up increasing the after-tax<br />

price of x, gener<strong>at</strong>ing a neg<strong>at</strong>ive income effect for all consumers. Appendix B expands the model to<br />

account for this possibility and identifies conditions under which the welfare results derived above are<br />

valid. We show th<strong>at</strong> a shift from register to posted taxes is most likely to result in a net increase in the<br />

after-tax price when supply is quite inelastic and demand is quite elastic. 7 As a result, the welfare results<br />

presented here are most applicable to goods for which demand is rel<strong>at</strong>ively inelastic and for which supply<br />

is rel<strong>at</strong>ively elastic – th<strong>at</strong> is, goods for which posted taxes are most likely to be passed on to consumers.<br />

II. Attentiveness to Cigarette Taxes by Income<br />

In Part I, we showed th<strong>at</strong> policymakers can manipul<strong>at</strong>e the salience of a tax to redistribute the tax’s<br />

burden between <strong>at</strong>tentive and in<strong>at</strong>tentive agents. In practice, policymakers are often concerned with<br />

how the burden of a tax is distributed by income. In particular, a concern with many commodity taxes<br />

is th<strong>at</strong> they are regressive – th<strong>at</strong> is, they constitute a disproportion<strong>at</strong>ely gre<strong>at</strong>er burden for low-income<br />

6 An immedi<strong>at</strong>e implic<strong>at</strong>ion of this result is th<strong>at</strong> the optimal register tax r<strong>at</strong>e is always non-zero.<br />

7 One way to understand the intuition behind these conditions is as follows. The incidence of a posted tax is shifted to<br />

producers when demand is elastic and supply is inelastic. Replacing a posted tax with a register tax effectively reduces the<br />

elasticity of consumer demand because some consumers are less sensitive to taxes imposed <strong>at</strong> the register. Consequently, when<br />

supply and demand for a good are such th<strong>at</strong> much of the burden of the posted tax falls on producers, the shift to a register tax<br />

will cause a large change in the distribution of the tax’s incidence.<br />

10<br />

> 0.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!