06.04.2013 Views

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

Goldin & Homonoff - DataSpace at Princeton University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Smoke Gets in Your Eyes: Cigarette Tax Salience and<br />

Regressivity<br />

Jacob <strong>Goldin</strong> T<strong>at</strong>iana <strong>Homonoff</strong> ∗<br />

August 10, 2011<br />

Abstract<br />

Recent evidence suggests consumers pay less <strong>at</strong>tention to commodity taxes th<strong>at</strong> are levied <strong>at</strong> the<br />

register than to taxes th<strong>at</strong> are included in a good’s posted price. If this <strong>at</strong>tention gap is larger for<br />

high-income consumers than for low-income consumers, policymakers can manipul<strong>at</strong>e a tax’s regressivity<br />

by altering the fraction of the tax imposed <strong>at</strong> the register. We investig<strong>at</strong>e income differences<br />

in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to cigarette taxes, exploiting st<strong>at</strong>e and time vari<strong>at</strong>ion in cigarette excise and sales tax<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es. Whereas all consumers respond to taxes th<strong>at</strong> appear in cigarettes’ posted price, only low-income<br />

consumers respond to taxes levied <strong>at</strong> the register.<br />

∗ <strong>Goldin</strong>: Department of Economics, <strong>Princeton</strong> <strong>University</strong>, Industrial Rel<strong>at</strong>ions Section, Firestone Library, <strong>Princeton</strong>, NJ<br />

08544-2098 (email: jgoldin@princeton.edu). <strong>Homonoff</strong>: Department of Economics, <strong>Princeton</strong> <strong>University</strong>, Industrial Rel<strong>at</strong>ions<br />

Section, Firestone Library, <strong>Princeton</strong>, NJ 08544-2098 (email: homonoff@princeton.edu). We gr<strong>at</strong>efully acknowledge<br />

Henry Farber, David Lee, Harvey Rosen, Raj Chetty, and Kory Kroft for reading earlier drafts of this paper and providing<br />

helpful feedback. We also thank Eliav Danziger, Ted Gayer, Jonah Gelbach, Michael Geruso, Nikolaj Harmon, Christine Jolls,<br />

Rohit Lamba, Abigail Sussman, Eldar Shafir, Dean Spears, and Paul Scott, as well as participants in the Industrial Rel<strong>at</strong>ions<br />

Sections Seminar and Public Finance Working Group <strong>at</strong> <strong>Princeton</strong> <strong>University</strong>, for convers<strong>at</strong>ions and suggestions th<strong>at</strong> have<br />

gre<strong>at</strong>ly improved the quality of this project. All errors are our own.<br />

1


Should governments levy commodity taxes <strong>at</strong> the register or include them in a good’s posted price?<br />

Traditional approaches to the economics of tax<strong>at</strong>ion offer little guidance to policymakers grappling with<br />

this question. Indeed, neoclassical theory suggests th<strong>at</strong> this aspect of tax design – the choice between<br />

“posted” and “register” taxes – does not affect consumer welfare because consumers correctly compute<br />

and account for all taxes th<strong>at</strong> will be assessed on a given transaction. However, a series of recent findings<br />

call th<strong>at</strong> invariance prediction into doubt. For example, Raj Chetty, Adam Looney, and Kory Kroft (CLK)<br />

(2009) present compelling evidence th<strong>at</strong> consumers pay more <strong>at</strong>tention to goods’ posted prices than to<br />

register taxes because the former are more salient – consumers see the posted tax-inclusive price when<br />

making their purchasing decisions. Rel<strong>at</strong>ed empirical findings by Amy N. Finkelstein (2009) and Marika<br />

I. Cabral and Caroline M. Hoxby (2010) are also consistent with the hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> the salience of a tax<br />

shapes the extent to which consumers perceive it. This line of research suggests th<strong>at</strong> the policy choice<br />

between posted and register taxes may not be as irrelevant as neoclassical theory predicts.<br />

This paper investig<strong>at</strong>es the distributional effects of the government’s choice between posted and reg-<br />

ister taxes. Part I considers the case in which consumers differ in their <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes – th<strong>at</strong><br />

is, when only some consumers take register taxes into account when making their purchasing decisions.<br />

Drawing on a stylized model of consumer behavior, we show how a revenue-neutral shift from posted to<br />

register taxes reduces the tax burden on <strong>at</strong>tentive consumers, unambiguously improving the welfare of<br />

th<strong>at</strong> group.<br />

We then turn to a practical implic<strong>at</strong>ion of this insight. A concern with many commodity taxes is<br />

th<strong>at</strong> they are regressive – they constitute a proportion<strong>at</strong>ely gre<strong>at</strong>er burden for low-income taxpayers.<br />

However, if low-income consumers pay more <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes than high-income consumers<br />

do, policymakers can reduce a tax’s regressivity by adding it <strong>at</strong> the register instead of including it in<br />

the commodity’s posted price. Conversely, when low-income consumers are rel<strong>at</strong>ively less <strong>at</strong>tentive to<br />

register taxes, reducing a tax’s salience will exacerb<strong>at</strong>e its regressivity. Hence, knowing how consumers’<br />

<strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes varies by income is essential for understanding the distribution of a tax’s<br />

burden.<br />

Part II investig<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> question empirically in the context of cigarette taxes. Cigarette purchases<br />

are typically subject to two types of taxes in the United St<strong>at</strong>es: an excise tax, which is included in the<br />

2


cigarette’s posted price, and a sales tax, which is added <strong>at</strong> the register. Drawing on individual survey<br />

d<strong>at</strong>a about cigarette consumption, we exploit st<strong>at</strong>e and time vari<strong>at</strong>ion in cigarette sales and excise tax<br />

r<strong>at</strong>es to estim<strong>at</strong>e the rel<strong>at</strong>ion between the two tax types and cigarette demand. We find th<strong>at</strong> both high-<br />

and low-income consumers respond to changes in the cigarette excise tax, but th<strong>at</strong> only low-income<br />

consumers respond to changes in the sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e on cigarettes. These results suggest th<strong>at</strong> in the case of<br />

cigarettes, <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes declines by income. In conjunction with the insights from Part<br />

I, our findings suggest th<strong>at</strong> a revenue-neutral shift from posted to register taxes could reduce the burden<br />

of the cigarette tax on low-income consumers.<br />

Because the choice between register and posted taxes is a practical question th<strong>at</strong> policymakers must<br />

confront, the lack of economic liter<strong>at</strong>ure on the topic is surprising. Although the recent paper by Chetty,<br />

Looney, and Kroft (discussed above) provides important insights into the rel<strong>at</strong>ive efficiency of posted and<br />

register taxes, our analysis builds on theirs by investig<strong>at</strong>ing how the choice between the two tax designs<br />

affects the distribution of the tax’s burden between consumers. In particular, the aggreg<strong>at</strong>e n<strong>at</strong>ure of<br />

their d<strong>at</strong>a preclude CLK from investig<strong>at</strong>ing heterogeneity in consumer <strong>at</strong>tentiveness – our focus here.<br />

Moreover, the welfare analytic tools developed in CLK are geared toward assessing the efficiency of a<br />

tax in the context of a represent<strong>at</strong>ive-agent, r<strong>at</strong>her than a tax faced by heterogeneous consumers. To our<br />

knowledge, our paper is the first in the liter<strong>at</strong>ure to investig<strong>at</strong>e the link between the salience of a tax and<br />

the distribution of its burden across consumers.<br />

Our paper also fits into a nascent behavioral liter<strong>at</strong>ure investig<strong>at</strong>ing heterogeneity in the extent to<br />

which individuals depart from neoclassical models of decision-making. For example, Crystal C. Hall<br />

(2010) documents income differences in the mental accounting heuristics th<strong>at</strong> individuals employ when<br />

making financial decisions. Similarly, Sendhil Mullain<strong>at</strong>han and Eldar Shafir (2009) argue th<strong>at</strong> a num-<br />

ber of behavioral phenomena affect the poor in distinctive ways because th<strong>at</strong> group lacks many of the<br />

resources used by higher-income consumers to improve decision-making quality (such as access to fi-<br />

nancial advising). In a different context, Kelly Shue and Erzo F. P. Luttmer (2009) present evidence th<strong>at</strong><br />

low-income voters are particularly prone to accidently selecting the wrong candid<strong>at</strong>e when voting ballots<br />

are designed in confusing ways. Our paper contributes to this growing liter<strong>at</strong>ure by exploring a particular<br />

context in which cognitive limit<strong>at</strong>ions faced by all decision-makers (e.g. bounded <strong>at</strong>tention and computa-<br />

3


tional abilities) affect high- and low-income consumers in distinctive ways. Most notably, whereas other<br />

studies have found devi<strong>at</strong>ions from optimal decision-making to be gre<strong>at</strong>est for low-income decision-<br />

makers, we find the opposite. At least in the context of cigarette tax<strong>at</strong>ion, it appears th<strong>at</strong> lower-income<br />

consumers do a better job of accounting for register taxes when making purchasing decisions.<br />

The paper is organized as follows. Part I constructs a stylized model of consumer behavior and<br />

uses it to analyze the welfare effects of a policy shift from posted to register taxes. The model takes<br />

as its starting point the assumption th<strong>at</strong> consumers differ in their <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes. Part II<br />

constitutes the core of the paper, an empirical investig<strong>at</strong>ion of th<strong>at</strong> assumption in the context of cigarette<br />

taxes. In particular, we investig<strong>at</strong>e whether high- and low-income consumers respond differently to<br />

cigarette register taxes, using those groups’ responsiveness to posted taxes on cigarettes as a baseline.<br />

Part III concludes.<br />

I. Tax Salience and Distribution<br />

Part I demonstr<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> when consumers differ in their <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes, the government’s<br />

choice between posted and register taxes affects the distribution of a tax’s burden. In particular, replacing<br />

a posted tax with a register tax increases total tax revenue because only <strong>at</strong>tentive agents consider the<br />

full after-tax price when determining their demand for x. Th<strong>at</strong> extra revenue accommod<strong>at</strong>es a reduction<br />

in the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e on x, gener<strong>at</strong>ing a positive income effect for <strong>at</strong>tentive consumers. In<strong>at</strong>tentive<br />

consumers also benefit from the reduction in the combined tax on x, but their welfare gains are offset by<br />

optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error induced by the register tax.<br />

Our modeling approach is similar to th<strong>at</strong> employed in Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007), except th<strong>at</strong><br />

we allow for heterogeneity in agents’ <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes. Suppose th<strong>at</strong> society is composed<br />

of two agents (A and B) who make consumption decisions between some good x, and a composite of all<br />

other goods, y. Good x is subject to both a register tax and a posted tax, whereas good y is left untaxed.<br />

Both agents pay <strong>at</strong>tention to posted taxes when making their consumption decisions, but only A takes<br />

register taxes into account. B ignores the register tax when choosing how much x to consume, tre<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

it as if it were zero. The agents share a utility function U(x,y), and both have budget constraints of the<br />

4


form<br />

BCi : (p +tp +tr)xi + yi ≤ Mi<br />

where the agent’s type is denoted by i ∈ {A,B}, p is the pre-tax price of x, tp is the posted tax r<strong>at</strong>e, tr is<br />

the register tax r<strong>at</strong>e, M is income, and the pre-tax price of y is normalized to one.<br />

Consumption is determined in two steps. First, agents choose their intended consumption bundle<br />

<br />

according to their perceived budget constraint BCi . A is <strong>at</strong>tentive to the register tax, so her perceived<br />

budget constraint m<strong>at</strong>ches her true budget constraint, BCA = BCA. In contrast, B misperceives the register<br />

tax to be zero: BCB : (p +tp)xi +yi ≤ Mi. The (x,y) pair th<strong>at</strong> maximizes utility subject to the agent’s per-<br />

ceived budget constraint is the intended consumption bundle (xi, yi). 1 Note th<strong>at</strong> B’s intended consumption<br />

bundle will be infeasible when it fails to s<strong>at</strong>isfy her true budget constraint.<br />

Because the bundle th<strong>at</strong> agents consume must ultim<strong>at</strong>ely be feasible, closing the model requires<br />

specifying the final consumption bundle for agents whose intended consumption bundle is infeasible.<br />

Because A chooses a feasible bundle to begin with, her final bundle always equals her intended bundle,<br />

(xA,yA) ≡ ( xA, yA). To pin down consumption for B, we assume th<strong>at</strong> agents who over-spend on x reduce<br />

their expenditures on y by the amount th<strong>at</strong> they overspent on x. In our not<strong>at</strong>ion: xB = xB and yB =<br />

MB − (p +tp +tr) xB. 2 This assumption is n<strong>at</strong>ural for the case in which y represents all goods other<br />

than x and agents make <strong>at</strong> least some of their consumption decisions after purchasing x; consumers who<br />

accidently overspend on x will have less income available to spend on their remaining purchases (which<br />

are all part of y). 3<br />

We are now in a position to link consumer demand to the tax r<strong>at</strong>es. Holding the posted price and<br />

agents’ income fixed, we can express demand as a function of the tax r<strong>at</strong>es, xi = xi (tp,tr) and yi =<br />

yi (tp,tr). For A, final consumption always equals intended consumption, so demand corresponds to the<br />

1 Th<strong>at</strong> is, (xi, yi) s<strong>at</strong>isfies argmax U(xi,yi) s.t. BCi holds.<br />

2 Note th<strong>at</strong> we are implicitly assuming x to be a small enough portion of total consumption so th<strong>at</strong> an agent’s intended<br />

consumption of x is never infeasible, even after taking the register tax into account.<br />

3 In principle, one could choose a different rule for mapping consumers’ sub-optimal decision-making into feasible consumption<br />

bundles. Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) identify three intuitive “budget adjustment rules”: the one th<strong>at</strong> we<br />

employ, as well as two others. Appendix A demonstr<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> the qualit<strong>at</strong>ive results in this section are robust to all three of<br />

those rules. More generally, the Appendix demonstr<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> our main result holds as long as individuals who misperceive the<br />

price of x to be lower than it really is end up alloc<strong>at</strong>ing more of their income to x and less of their income to y rel<strong>at</strong>ive to the<br />

case where they take the true after-tax price of x into account.<br />

5<br />

(1)


solution of the standard utility maximiz<strong>at</strong>ion problem:<br />

(xA,yA) = argmax<br />

x,y U(x,y) s.t. BCA. (2)<br />

Because the tax r<strong>at</strong>es do not enter the utility function directly and because they appear symmetrically in<br />

the budget constraint, A’s demand will depend only on the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e – whether it takes the form<br />

of a register or posted tax does not m<strong>at</strong>ter. Hence we can write xA (tp,tr) = xA (tp +tr,0), or xA (tp +tr) for<br />

short. And similarly for y: yA (tp,tr) = yA (tp +tr) = MA −(p +tp +tr)xA (tp +tr), where the last equality<br />

follows from A’s budget constraint. Note th<strong>at</strong> in accordance with the neoclassical model’s prediction, we<br />

have ∂xA<br />

∂tr<br />

= ∂xA<br />

∂tp<br />

= ∂xA<br />

∂ p .<br />

In contrast, B’s intended consumption bundle will not m<strong>at</strong>ch B’s final consumption bundle whenever<br />

the register tax r<strong>at</strong>e is positive. Because all of the income overspent on x comes out of expenditures<br />

intended for y, we have xB (tp,tr) = xB (tp,tr) for all values of tp and tr. Since B’s intended consumption<br />

of x is insensitive to register taxes, xB (tp,tr) = xB (tp,t ′ r) for all tr and t ′ r, it must also be the case th<strong>at</strong> B’s<br />

final consumption of x is insensitive to register taxes, xB (tp,tr) = xB (tp,t ′ r) for all tr and t ′ r. In particular,<br />

this result holds for t ′ r = 0. Hence, we can write xB (tp,tr) = xB (tp,0) ≡ xB (tp). In words, B’s demand for<br />

x under any non-zero register tax corresponds to B’s optimal demand for x in the special case where the<br />

register tax is zero.<br />

Using B’s true budget constraint, we can derive B’s final consumption of y:<br />

yB (tp,tr) = MB − (p +tp +tr)xB (tp). (3)<br />

Note th<strong>at</strong> in contrast to the neoclassical model, B responds differently to the two types of taxes: ∂xB<br />

∂tp =<br />

∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

= ∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

= 0.<br />

To incorpor<strong>at</strong>e tax policy into the model, consider a government th<strong>at</strong> must raise a fixed amount of<br />

revenue, R, from register and posted taxes on x. How does the government’s choice between register and<br />

posted taxes affect the well-being of the agents? In particular, we focus on the effects of a revenue-neutral<br />

increase in the register tax – th<strong>at</strong> is, an increase in the register tax coupled with a reduction in the posted<br />

tax by an amount th<strong>at</strong> keeps total revenue constant (<strong>at</strong> R). Let R denote total revenue collected by the two<br />

6


tax types:<br />

R(tp,tr) = (tp +tr)(xA + xB). (4)<br />

If both agents were fully <strong>at</strong>tentive to both types of tax, a revenue-neutral one dollar increase in the register<br />

tax would require a one dollar decrease in the posted tax; changing the balance between register and<br />

posted taxes would not affect the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e necessary to raise a given amount of revenue. When<br />

some agents are in<strong>at</strong>tentive, however, the demand reduction th<strong>at</strong> typically accompanies a tax increase<br />

will be muted. As a result, an incremental increase in the posted tax will, all else equal, raise less revenue<br />

than an incremental increase in the register tax: 4<br />

∂R<br />

∂tp<br />

<br />

∂xA ∂xB<br />

= (xA + xB) + (tp +tr) +<br />

∂ p ∂ p<br />

<br />

∂xA<br />

< (xA + xB) + (tp +tr) =<br />

∂ p<br />

∂R<br />

∂tr<br />

The reduction in the posted tax associ<strong>at</strong>ed with a revenue-neutral increase in the register tax can be<br />

found by totally differenti<strong>at</strong>ing the government’s budget constraint and solving for ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

:<br />

R<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

= −<br />

Note th<strong>at</strong> the denomin<strong>at</strong>or is positive as long as ∂R(tp,tr)<br />

∂tp<br />

raising the tax r<strong>at</strong>e would actually decrease revenue.<br />

xA + xB + (tp +tr) ∂xA<br />

∂ p<br />

xA + xB + (tp +tr) ∂xA<br />

∂ p + (tp +tr) ∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

∂tr<br />

. (5)<br />

> 0, i.e., th<strong>at</strong> demand is not so sensitive th<strong>at</strong><br />

How does a revenue-neutral increase in the register tax affect the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e, tp + tr? The<br />

effect of the shift is given by d(tp+tr)<br />

<br />

<br />

= dtr R ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

+1. Because demand is downward-sloping ( ∂tr R ∂xB<br />

∂ p < 0), (5)<br />

implies th<strong>at</strong> ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

< −1. Consequently, a revenue-neutral increase in the register tax is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with<br />

∂tr R <br />

<br />

< 0.<br />

R<br />

an overall reduction in the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e, d(tp+tr)<br />

dtr<br />

Wh<strong>at</strong> are the welfare effects of a revenue-neutral shift towards register taxes? Indirect utility is given<br />

by Vi (tp,tr) = U (xi (tp,tr),yi (tp,tr)). The welfare effect of the shift is thus:<br />

<br />

dVi <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

<br />

∂xi<br />

= Ux (xi,yi) +<br />

∂tr<br />

∂xi<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

∂yi<br />

+Uy (xi,yi) +<br />

∂tp ∂tr<br />

∂tr<br />

∂yi<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

<br />

∂tp ∂tr<br />

4 The 2-good n<strong>at</strong>ure of the model guarantees ∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

< 0.<br />

R<br />

7<br />

R


First, consider the effect of the shift on A’s welfare. Recall th<strong>at</strong> ∂xA ∂xA ∂xA = = ∂tr ∂tp ∂ p<br />

R<br />

R<br />

R<br />

so th<strong>at</strong><br />

<br />

<br />

dVA <br />

= Ux (xA,yA) 1 +<br />

dtr<br />

∂tp<br />

<br />

∂xA <br />

∂tr ∂ p +Uy<br />

<br />

(xA,yA) 1 + ∂tp<br />

<br />

∂yA <br />

∂tr ∂ p<br />

Differenti<strong>at</strong>ing A’s budget constraint with respect to p yields ∂yA<br />

∂ p = −x − (p +tp +tr) ∂xA<br />

∂ p<br />

assuming th<strong>at</strong> (xA,yA) constitutes an interior solution in A’s budget set, we have<br />

Ux (xA,yA) = (p +tp +tr)Uy (xA,yA).<br />

. Additionally,<br />

Substituting both of these pieces into the above expression and cancelling terms yields the effect of the<br />

shift on A’s welfare:<br />

<br />

dVA <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

<br />

d(tp +tr) <br />

= −Uy (xA,yA)xA<br />

. (6)<br />

dtr<br />

Because we know th<strong>at</strong> a revenue-neutral shift towards register taxes reduces the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e,<br />

<br />

<br />

< 0, we can conclude th<strong>at</strong> the shift unambiguously increases the welfare of the <strong>at</strong>tentive agent.<br />

R<br />

d(tp+tr)<br />

dtr<br />

This is the main result of the section, and the intuition is straightforward. Replacing a posted tax with<br />

a register tax raises total revenue because only <strong>at</strong>tentive agents reduce their demand for x in response to<br />

the higher after-tax price. The extra revenue accommod<strong>at</strong>es a reduction in the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e on x,<br />

gener<strong>at</strong>ing a positive income effect for <strong>at</strong>tentive consumers. 5<br />

Wh<strong>at</strong> about the in<strong>at</strong>tentive agent? The change in utility for B from a revenue-neutral shift towards<br />

register taxes is given by<br />

<br />

dVB <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

= Ux (xB,yB) ∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

R<br />

<br />

∂yB<br />

+Uy (xB,yB)<br />

∂ p<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

+ ∂yB<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

Differenti<strong>at</strong>ing B’s budget constraint with respect to the price and the register tax yields:<br />

∂yB<br />

∂ p = −x − (p +tp +tr) ∂xB<br />

∂ p and<br />

5 This result can be weakened by endogenizing agents’ decisions about whether to pay <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes. If a small<br />

increase in the register tax causes a large number of formerly in<strong>at</strong>tentive agents to start taking register taxes into account, the<br />

shift might necessit<strong>at</strong>e an increase in the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e. In such cases, the shift to register taxes would actually gener<strong>at</strong>e<br />

a neg<strong>at</strong>ive income effect, reducing the welfare of all agents. Consequently, the results presented here are most applicable to<br />

situ<strong>at</strong>ions in which small changes in the tax r<strong>at</strong>e do not induce dram<strong>at</strong>ic shifts in which agents are <strong>at</strong>tentive.<br />

8


∂yB<br />

= −x.<br />

∂tr<br />

Substituting those conditions into the above expression gives the effect of the shift on B’s welfare:<br />

<br />

<br />

dVB <br />

d(tp <br />

+tr) <br />

= −Uy (xB,yB)xB +<br />

dtr<br />

dtr<br />

∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

R<br />

R<br />

∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

ε (7)<br />

where ε ≡ Ux (xB,yB) − (p +tr +tp)Uy (xB,yB) represents optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error from B’s in<strong>at</strong>tention to the<br />

register tax. Because B consumes too much x and too little y rel<strong>at</strong>ive to her optimal quantity, declining<br />

marginal utility in x and y implies th<strong>at</strong> ε < 0.<br />

From (7), we can see th<strong>at</strong> the net welfare effect on in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers is ambiguous. Like the<br />

<strong>at</strong>tentive consumer, B benefits because the shift lowers the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e. On the other hand, by<br />

raising the register tax, the shift pushes B further from her optimal consumption bundle. In general,<br />

either of these effects may domin<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

Th<strong>at</strong> even in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers can be made better off by a shift towards register taxes is somewh<strong>at</strong><br />

surprising. The explan<strong>at</strong>ion is th<strong>at</strong> for low register tax r<strong>at</strong>es, the welfare loss caused by optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

error is small (the marginal utilities of expenditures on x and y are similar), but the income effect from<br />

the lower combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e may still be substantial. To develop this intuition, let (x∗ B ,y∗B ) represent the<br />

(interior) optimal bundle in B’s true budget set, th<strong>at</strong> is, the consumption bundle th<strong>at</strong> B would choose were<br />

she to take the register tax into account. Assume th<strong>at</strong> utility is additively separable in x and y so th<strong>at</strong><br />

ε = Ux (xB) − (p +tp +tr)Uy (yB). Taking first-order Taylor approxim<strong>at</strong>ions around (x∗ B ,y∗B ) and using<br />

the fact th<strong>at</strong> the pair (x∗ B ,y∗ B ) s<strong>at</strong>isfies the first order condition Ux (x∗ B ) = (p +tr +tp)Uy (y∗ B ), we can write<br />

ε ≈ γ (xB − x ∗ B)<br />

where γ ≡ Uxx (x ∗ B ) + (p +tr +tp) 2 Uyy (y ∗ B ). Additionally, taking the Taylor approxim<strong>at</strong>ion of x∗ B (tp,tr)<br />

around tr = 0, and using the fact th<strong>at</strong> x ∗ B (tp,0) = xB (tp,0) implies<br />

(xB − x ∗ ∂xB<br />

B) ≈ −tr<br />

∂ p .<br />

9


Substituting these conditions into (7) gives<br />

<br />

dVB <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

> 0 iff Uy (xB,yB)xB − tr<br />

tr +tp<br />

∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

γ ∂R<br />

∂tr<br />

When register taxes are zero, the distortion caused by the optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error will also be zero and<br />

hence the effect on B’s welfare will be positive. 6 When register taxes represent a large fraction of the<br />

total tax on x, a further shift in th<strong>at</strong> direction can reduce B’s welfare by exacerb<strong>at</strong>ing her optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

error. So although shifting towards a register tax always benefits <strong>at</strong>tentive consumers, the welfare effect<br />

for in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers depends on the fraction of the combined tax currently imposed <strong>at</strong> the register.<br />

For simplicity, we have assumed th<strong>at</strong> the pre-tax price of x is fixed <strong>at</strong> p. In reality, firms may adjust the<br />

price they charge for x in response to changes in the type of tax imposed. If a shift from posted to register<br />

taxes induced firms to raise p by a sufficient quantity, the policy could end up increasing the after-tax<br />

price of x, gener<strong>at</strong>ing a neg<strong>at</strong>ive income effect for all consumers. Appendix B expands the model to<br />

account for this possibility and identifies conditions under which the welfare results derived above are<br />

valid. We show th<strong>at</strong> a shift from register to posted taxes is most likely to result in a net increase in the<br />

after-tax price when supply is quite inelastic and demand is quite elastic. 7 As a result, the welfare results<br />

presented here are most applicable to goods for which demand is rel<strong>at</strong>ively inelastic and for which supply<br />

is rel<strong>at</strong>ively elastic – th<strong>at</strong> is, goods for which posted taxes are most likely to be passed on to consumers.<br />

II. Attentiveness to Cigarette Taxes by Income<br />

In Part I, we showed th<strong>at</strong> policymakers can manipul<strong>at</strong>e the salience of a tax to redistribute the tax’s<br />

burden between <strong>at</strong>tentive and in<strong>at</strong>tentive agents. In practice, policymakers are often concerned with<br />

how the burden of a tax is distributed by income. In particular, a concern with many commodity taxes<br />

is th<strong>at</strong> they are regressive – th<strong>at</strong> is, they constitute a disproportion<strong>at</strong>ely gre<strong>at</strong>er burden for low-income<br />

6 An immedi<strong>at</strong>e implic<strong>at</strong>ion of this result is th<strong>at</strong> the optimal register tax r<strong>at</strong>e is always non-zero.<br />

7 One way to understand the intuition behind these conditions is as follows. The incidence of a posted tax is shifted to<br />

producers when demand is elastic and supply is inelastic. Replacing a posted tax with a register tax effectively reduces the<br />

elasticity of consumer demand because some consumers are less sensitive to taxes imposed <strong>at</strong> the register. Consequently, when<br />

supply and demand for a good are such th<strong>at</strong> much of the burden of the posted tax falls on producers, the shift to a register tax<br />

will cause a large change in the distribution of the tax’s incidence.<br />

10<br />

> 0.


consumers. An implic<strong>at</strong>ion of the results in Part I is th<strong>at</strong> if the poor tend to pay more <strong>at</strong>tention to register<br />

taxes than the rich, a shift towards register taxes will make a commodity tax more progressive. On the<br />

other hand, if low-income consumers are less <strong>at</strong>tentive to register taxes, such a shift would exacerb<strong>at</strong>e<br />

the tax’s regressivity. As such, it is important to determine whether <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes varies by<br />

income, and if so, whether high- or low-income consumers are the more <strong>at</strong>tentive.<br />

In Part II, we undertake th<strong>at</strong> task in the context of cigarette taxes. There are good reasons to expect<br />

th<strong>at</strong> low-income consumers will be more <strong>at</strong>tentive to register taxes on cigarettes. In particular, the utility<br />

cost of optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion errors will tend to be gre<strong>at</strong>er for those with less income to spend on other goods. As a<br />

result, low-income consumers should be particularly motiv<strong>at</strong>ed to spend the effort required to take register<br />

taxes into account. On the other hand, other factors could push high consumers to pay more <strong>at</strong>tention<br />

to register taxes. For example, because the rich tend to consume more of each good, the magnitude of<br />

their optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion errors will tend be gre<strong>at</strong>er as well. Appendix C utilizes a cognitive cost model to<br />

explore these tensions more formally. For the case of cigarettes, the analysis suggests th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness<br />

to cigarette register taxes is likely to decline by income. 8 However, because it is difficult to predict which<br />

group will be more <strong>at</strong>tentive on the basis of theory alone, the remainder of Part II is primarily empirical.<br />

Our goal is to investig<strong>at</strong>e whether low-income cigarette consumers are more <strong>at</strong>tentive to register<br />

taxes than high-income consumers are. Cigarette purchases are subjected to two types of tax in the<br />

United St<strong>at</strong>es: an excise tax, which consumers see reflected in the posted price, and a sales tax, which<br />

is typically added <strong>at</strong> the register. We use st<strong>at</strong>e and time vari<strong>at</strong>ion in these tax r<strong>at</strong>es to estim<strong>at</strong>e how<br />

consumers respond to each type of tax. We assume th<strong>at</strong> consumers fully account for posted taxes, so th<strong>at</strong><br />

in<strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes can be measured by the gap between consumers’ responsiveness to register<br />

taxes and their responsiveness to posted taxes.<br />

Part II is structured as follows. We begin by investig<strong>at</strong>ing whether the general popul<strong>at</strong>ion appears<br />

to pay more <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes than to posted taxes on cigarettes. The analysis applies the basic<br />

empirical str<strong>at</strong>egy of CLK to a new product (cigarettes instead of beer) and <strong>at</strong> a different unit of obser-<br />

v<strong>at</strong>ion (individual instead of aggreg<strong>at</strong>e consumption d<strong>at</strong>a). We then turn to our central question, whether<br />

<strong>at</strong>tentiveness to cigarette register taxes differs by income, which we assess empirically by interacting the<br />

8 The framework we develop does not make a uniform prediction for all goods, but r<strong>at</strong>her highlights the factors th<strong>at</strong><br />

determine which income group will be more <strong>at</strong>tentive to register taxes on a particular good. In general, high-income consumers<br />

tend to be less <strong>at</strong>tentive to register taxes on goods, like cigarettes, for which demand is rel<strong>at</strong>ively insensitive to income.<br />

11


excise and sales tax variables with respondents’ income. Finally, we undertake a number of robustness<br />

tests to investig<strong>at</strong>e whether our results actually reflect heterogeneous <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes as<br />

opposed to various altern<strong>at</strong>ive explan<strong>at</strong>ions.<br />

A. D<strong>at</strong>a<br />

We obtain cross-sectional micro d<strong>at</strong>a on cigarette consumption from the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveil-<br />

lance System (BRFSS), supported by the N<strong>at</strong>ional Center for Chronic Disease Prevention and Health<br />

Promotion and the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. The BRFSS is a st<strong>at</strong>e-based telephone<br />

survey system th<strong>at</strong> tracks health conditions and risk behaviors of individuals 18 years and older. The<br />

number of st<strong>at</strong>es particip<strong>at</strong>ing in the survey has grown over time, from 15 in 1984 to 50 in 1994 (as well<br />

as the District of Columbia). To reduce the potential for the changing composition of st<strong>at</strong>es to bias our<br />

results, we restrict our analysis to the st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> have been in the sample since 1987. 9 We also follow<br />

CLK by dropping two st<strong>at</strong>es from the analysis: Hawaii, because sales taxes in th<strong>at</strong> st<strong>at</strong>e are included in<br />

the posted price, and West Virginia, because of frequent changes to th<strong>at</strong> st<strong>at</strong>e’s sales tax base over the<br />

sample period. After dropping observ<strong>at</strong>ions th<strong>at</strong> are missing demographic variables, our final d<strong>at</strong>aset<br />

contains approxim<strong>at</strong>ely one million observ<strong>at</strong>ions. Because the survey disproportion<strong>at</strong>ely samples certain<br />

groups, we use weighted regressions to obtain represent<strong>at</strong>ive estim<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

The BRFSS d<strong>at</strong>a contains two measures of smoking demand: whether the respondent is a smoker<br />

(smokes <strong>at</strong> least one cigarette every day) and how many cigarettes the respondent typically consumes<br />

each day. Although the BRFSS questionnaire asked respondents about smoking particip<strong>at</strong>ion in each year<br />

of the survey, d<strong>at</strong>a on the number of cigarettes consumed are only available through 2000. Consequently,<br />

our analysis restricts the sample to those interviewed between 1984 and 2000. The BRFSS also collects<br />

inform<strong>at</strong>ion on a number of demographic variables, including income. 10<br />

9 The 17 st<strong>at</strong>es we drop for this reason are: AK, AR, CO, DE, IA, KS, LA, MI, MS, NJ, NV, OK, OR, PA, VA, VT, WY.<br />

The remaining st<strong>at</strong>es constitute 75% of the U.S. popul<strong>at</strong>ion in 2000. The qualit<strong>at</strong>ive story is unchanged by employing an<br />

altern<strong>at</strong>ive cutoff year or using the full range of available st<strong>at</strong>es.<br />

10 We make use of inform<strong>at</strong>ion concerning the respondent’s age, race, sex, educ<strong>at</strong>ional <strong>at</strong>tainment, marital st<strong>at</strong>us, employment<br />

st<strong>at</strong>us, and income. Household income is measured in terms of income-c<strong>at</strong>egories. Two problems arise when using this<br />

variable. First, the income measure is top-coded <strong>at</strong> a rel<strong>at</strong>ively low value ($75,000 for much of our sample period). Second,<br />

the income c<strong>at</strong>egories are not adjusted for infl<strong>at</strong>ion, making it difficult to compare respondents in the same c<strong>at</strong>egory over<br />

time. R<strong>at</strong>her than <strong>at</strong>tempt to convert the BRFSS income c<strong>at</strong>egory d<strong>at</strong>a into a measure of real income, we measure income in<br />

percentile terms, assigning respondents the midpoint of the percentiles of their income c<strong>at</strong>egory boundaries. For example, if<br />

12


D<strong>at</strong>a on st<strong>at</strong>e-level cigarette excise tax r<strong>at</strong>es, sales tax r<strong>at</strong>es, and average cigarette prices were obtained<br />

from the Tax Burden on Tobacco 2008 report, published by Orzechowski and Walker (and previously by<br />

the Tobacco Institute). We g<strong>at</strong>hered inform<strong>at</strong>ion on the exact d<strong>at</strong>e of enactment of sales tax changes<br />

from a number of sources including the World Tax D<strong>at</strong>abase (<strong>University</strong> of Michigan), st<strong>at</strong>e government<br />

websites, and archives of local newspaper accounts. Following convention, our measure of st<strong>at</strong>e tax r<strong>at</strong>es<br />

includes local taxes to the extent th<strong>at</strong> they are uniform across the st<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

Whereas the sales tax is an ad valorem tax (consumers are charged a fixed fraction of a good’s price),<br />

the excise tax is a unit tax (consumers pay a set dollar amount per pack, regardless of the pre-tax price).<br />

In order to make the two types of taxes comparable for the empirical analysis, we convert the excise tax<br />

to an ad valorem tax using the method described in CLK. 11<br />

Both sales and excise taxes increased between 1984 and 2000 (Figures 1a and 1b). In 1984, 38 st<strong>at</strong>es<br />

imposed sales taxes on cigarettes, and the median sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e was 4 percent. By 2000, 45 st<strong>at</strong>es imposed<br />

sales taxes on cigarettes, and the median sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e had climbed to 5 percent. Similarly, median st<strong>at</strong>e<br />

excise taxes on cigarettes increased from 14 cents in 1984 to 34 cents in 2000. In addition, the federal<br />

excise tax on cigarettes increased three times over the same period, climbing from 16 to 34 cents per<br />

pack. Table I presents summary st<strong>at</strong>istics.<br />

Figure 2 shows th<strong>at</strong> aggreg<strong>at</strong>e cigarette consumption in the United St<strong>at</strong>es declined between 1984 and<br />

2000. Th<strong>at</strong> decline, however, was not uniform across the popul<strong>at</strong>ion. Figure 3 separ<strong>at</strong>ely plots smoking<br />

particip<strong>at</strong>ion r<strong>at</strong>es over time for the highest and lowest income quartiles. Low-income individuals were<br />

more likely to smoke than high-income ones in 1984, and th<strong>at</strong> gap widened over time.<br />

B. Attentiveness to Cigarette Taxes in the General Popul<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

We begin our empirical analysis by investig<strong>at</strong>ing whether consumers in the general popul<strong>at</strong>ion respond<br />

differently to register and posted taxes on cigarettes. The neoclassical model predicts th<strong>at</strong> the salience<br />

of a tax (e.g., whether it is included in the posted price or added <strong>at</strong> the register) should not affect how<br />

10 percent of the sample in one year reports an income between zero and $10,000, all individuals in th<strong>at</strong> income c<strong>at</strong>egory in<br />

th<strong>at</strong> year are assigned a value of 0.05.<br />

11 We divide the excise tax by the average n<strong>at</strong>ional price of a pack of cigarettes in 2000, adjusted for infl<strong>at</strong>ion. The r<strong>at</strong>ionale<br />

for using the infl<strong>at</strong>ion-adjusted n<strong>at</strong>ional price in 2000 as a proxy for the true price is to avoid endogeneity problems arising<br />

from the fact th<strong>at</strong> changes in cigarette prices are likely correl<strong>at</strong>ed with unobserved shocks to smoking demand.<br />

13


consumers respond to it. To see this formally, suppose th<strong>at</strong> demand for a good x depends on a consumer’s<br />

income I and the price of x, px:<br />

x = x(px,I).<br />

Purchases of x are subject to both a sales tax and an excise tax, so th<strong>at</strong> the final price of x is given by<br />

px = p(1 + t)(1 + s), in which p is the pre-tax price of x, t is the excise tax r<strong>at</strong>e, and s is the sales tax<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e. 12<br />

Because the excise and sales tax affect the price of x symmetrically, we have th<strong>at</strong><br />

∂x ∂x<br />

=<br />

∂ log(1 +t) ∂ log px<br />

∂ log px ∂x<br />

=<br />

∂ log(1 +t) ∂ log px<br />

∂ log px<br />

∂ log(1 + s) =<br />

∂x<br />

∂ log(1 + s)<br />

In words, how consumers adjust their demand for x in response to a tax change should not depend on<br />

whether the change occurred in the excise tax r<strong>at</strong>e or the sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e. 13<br />

CLK assess this prediction for the case of beer by linking changes in aggreg<strong>at</strong>e beer consumption<br />

by st<strong>at</strong>e to changes in the st<strong>at</strong>e’s sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e and excise tax on beer. They find th<strong>at</strong> changes in the<br />

beer excise tax are neg<strong>at</strong>ively and significantly correl<strong>at</strong>ed with changes in beer consumption, whereas<br />

sales tax changes appear to have little effect. As a result, CLK conclude th<strong>at</strong> the neoclassical model is<br />

mistaken and th<strong>at</strong> the salience of a tax affects how consumers respond. Because they lack disaggreg<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

consumption d<strong>at</strong>a, CLK are unable to assess whether the salience of a tax affects different parts of the<br />

popul<strong>at</strong>ion differently, our goal in Section II.C.<br />

Our analysis in this section differs from CLK by focusing on cigarettes instead of beer and by using<br />

individual survey d<strong>at</strong>a r<strong>at</strong>her than aggreg<strong>at</strong>e st<strong>at</strong>e consumption d<strong>at</strong>a. Our baseline empirical model takes<br />

the form:<br />

yismt = α + β1τ e smt + β2τ s smt + γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + πm + εismt<br />

where the unit of observ<strong>at</strong>ion is an individual i in st<strong>at</strong>e s, calendar month m, and year t. The dependent<br />

12 Some st<strong>at</strong>es do not include the excise tax in the price used to calcul<strong>at</strong>e the sales tax, so th<strong>at</strong> final prices are given by<br />

px = p(1 + t + s). Because the excise and sales tax still affect the price of x symmetrically in such st<strong>at</strong>es, the neoclassical<br />

model predicts th<strong>at</strong> demand should respond identically to sales and excise tax changes of the same proportion.<br />

13 Two assumptions are important for this result: first, th<strong>at</strong> tax r<strong>at</strong>es only enter consumer utility through their effect on<br />

product prices, and second, th<strong>at</strong> px is the only price th<strong>at</strong> affects demand for x. We maintain the first assumption throughout<br />

but consider the implic<strong>at</strong>ions of relaxing the second in Section II.E.<br />

14<br />

(8)


variable (y) represents cigarette demand, τ e is the log excise tax r<strong>at</strong>e, τ s is the log sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e, x are<br />

covari<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> do not vary between individuals interviewed in the same st<strong>at</strong>e, month, and year, and z<br />

are individual-level covari<strong>at</strong>es. We include st<strong>at</strong>e fixed effects µs to capture unobserved factors th<strong>at</strong> are<br />

correl<strong>at</strong>ed with both st<strong>at</strong>e tax r<strong>at</strong>es and the level of smoking demand. Year fixed effects λt capture time<br />

trends in smoking demand as well as yearly shocks to n<strong>at</strong>ional cigarette consumption, such as a n<strong>at</strong>ional<br />

anti-smoking campaign. Finally, πm is a calendar month effect, which accounts for seasonal or monthly<br />

p<strong>at</strong>terns in cigarette demand.<br />

As is standard in the cigarette demand liter<strong>at</strong>ure, 14 we model the decision of whether an individual<br />

smokes (the extensive margin) separ<strong>at</strong>ely from the decision of how much to smoke, conditional on being<br />

a smoker (the intensive margin). Consequently, in some specific<strong>at</strong>ions y is a binary choice variable<br />

indic<strong>at</strong>ing whether the individual reports being a smoker, and in other specific<strong>at</strong>ions y is the non-zero<br />

count of the number of cigarettes consumed in the last month, where the sample is restricted to self-<br />

reported smokers. This “double-hurdle” model is common in the cigarette demand liter<strong>at</strong>ure because the<br />

decision of whether to smoke may be fundamentally different than the decision of how much to smoke,<br />

and is inform<strong>at</strong>ive as to whether taxes affect consumption by turning smokers into non-smokers or by<br />

inducing current smokers to reduce the number of cigarettes they smoke. 15<br />

Table II presents the results of this analysis. 16 The specific<strong>at</strong>ions in Columns 1 and 4 regress smoking<br />

demand on the two tax r<strong>at</strong>es, individual demographic variables, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month<br />

fixed-effects. Since st<strong>at</strong>e taxes are often increased to meet budgetary shortfalls in bad economic times, it<br />

is likely th<strong>at</strong> tax r<strong>at</strong>e changes are correl<strong>at</strong>ed with st<strong>at</strong>e-level economic variables th<strong>at</strong> are not captured by<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e fixed effects. If cigarette consumption is also correl<strong>at</strong>ed with the business cycle, this omitted variable<br />

could bias our results. To account for this possibility, Columns 2 and 5 include st<strong>at</strong>e-level measures of<br />

real income and unemployment r<strong>at</strong>e. 17<br />

14See Frank J. Chaloupka and Kenneth E. Warner (2000) for a helpful review of the extensive liter<strong>at</strong>ure on estim<strong>at</strong>ing<br />

cigarette demand.<br />

15A drawback of the two-part approach is th<strong>at</strong> estim<strong>at</strong>ion results for the intensive margin may be biased by changes to the<br />

composition of the smoking popul<strong>at</strong>ion. We investig<strong>at</strong>e the robustness of this specific<strong>at</strong>ion in Section II.E.2.<br />

16We estim<strong>at</strong>e demand on the extensive margin with a linear probability model. A Probit model yields similar results.<br />

Because unobserved shocks to smoking demand may be correl<strong>at</strong>ed across time for consumers living in the same st<strong>at</strong>e, all<br />

tables report standard errors th<strong>at</strong> are clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level.<br />

17Real st<strong>at</strong>e income d<strong>at</strong>a comes from the Bureau of Economic Analysis and the st<strong>at</strong>e unemployment r<strong>at</strong>e d<strong>at</strong>a comes from<br />

the Bureau of Labor St<strong>at</strong>istics. Both variables are measured quarterly.<br />

15


Columns 3 and 6 add an interaction between income and a linear time trend. To motiv<strong>at</strong>e this addi-<br />

tion, recall th<strong>at</strong> smoking particip<strong>at</strong>ion r<strong>at</strong>es fell more steeply over the sample period for higher income<br />

consumers (Figure 3). Although this decline might stem from rising tax r<strong>at</strong>es over the sample period, it<br />

could also reflect a secular trend in smoking consumption <strong>at</strong> the top of the income spectrum, such as a<br />

shift in cultural <strong>at</strong>titudes about smoking among high SES individuals. Because tax r<strong>at</strong>es trend upwards<br />

over the sample period, a secular trend in smoking demand among high-income consumers could be<br />

confl<strong>at</strong>ed with the two tax-income interaction terms in the regression. The inclusion of the time trend in<br />

Columns 3 and 6 accounts for this possibility.<br />

The regressions in Table II show the effect of taxes on the intensive and extensive margins separ<strong>at</strong>ely.<br />

In order to provide a better picture of the overall effect of a tax change on cigarette demand, Table III<br />

follows the procedure laid out in McDonald and Moffitt (1980) to combine the intensive and extensive<br />

margin estim<strong>at</strong>es. In particular, one can decompose the conditional expect<strong>at</strong>ion of cigarette demand into<br />

its intensive and extensive components:<br />

E[y|x] = E[y|x,y > 0] ∗ P(y > 0|x),<br />

where y represents cigarette demand and x represents the covari<strong>at</strong>es. Using the product rule, the total<br />

effect of a change in one of the covari<strong>at</strong>es on cigarette demand is given by:<br />

∂E[y|x]<br />

∂x<br />

= ∂E[y|x,y > 0]<br />

∂x<br />

∗ P(y > 0|x) +<br />

∂P(y > 0|x)<br />

∂x<br />

∗ E[y|x,y > 0].<br />

By utilizing sample estim<strong>at</strong>es of P(y > 0|x) and E[y|x,y > 0], evalu<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong> the sample mean of each<br />

covari<strong>at</strong>e, we can combine the estim<strong>at</strong>ed coefficients from the intensive and extensive margin regressions<br />

into a rough estim<strong>at</strong>e of the overall effect of the taxes on cigarette demand. 18<br />

The results in Tables II and III are consistent with a salience effect on the intensive margin: a one-<br />

percent increase in the cigarette excise tax is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with an average reduction of 6.5 cigarettes per<br />

month among smokers, whereas the point estim<strong>at</strong>e on the sales tax term is less than half th<strong>at</strong> magnitude<br />

18 When calcul<strong>at</strong>ing standard errors for the aggreg<strong>at</strong>e effect, we ignore uncertainty in the sample averages of P(y > 0|x)<br />

and E[y|x,y > 0]. This approxim<strong>at</strong>ion is reasonable because the size of our sample guarantees those quantities are estim<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

precisely.<br />

16


and is not st<strong>at</strong>istically significant. However, the coefficient on the sales tax is measured imprecisely,<br />

and consequently, we cannot reject the null hypothesis of equality between the two coefficients. On the<br />

extensive margin, however, the point estim<strong>at</strong>e of the sales tax is slightly gre<strong>at</strong>er in magnitude than th<strong>at</strong><br />

of the excise tax, although here too the difference is not st<strong>at</strong>istically significant. Overall, the evidence is<br />

inconclusive regarding the presence of a salience effect for the general popul<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

C. Attentiveness to Cigarette Taxes by Income<br />

The inconclusive results for the general popul<strong>at</strong>ion in Section II.B might mask heterogeneous effects<br />

across income groups. We now turn to our primary question of interest, whether low-income consumers<br />

are particularly <strong>at</strong>tentive to cigarette register taxes. The baseline empirical model for this section is given<br />

by:<br />

yismt = α + β1τ e smt + β2τ s smt + ρ1τ e smtLIismt + ρ2τ s smtLIismt + ηLIismt +<br />

γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + πm + εismt<br />

where LI is a binary variable indic<strong>at</strong>ing whether the respondent is low-income, defined as having income<br />

below the 25th percentile. Compared to the econometric model in II.2, this specific<strong>at</strong>ion adds interaction<br />

terms between low-income st<strong>at</strong>us and the two tax r<strong>at</strong>e variables. 19 The coefficients on the two tax types,<br />

β1 and β2, describe how high-income consumers modify their demand in response to changes in the<br />

excise and sales taxes, respectively. In turn, the coefficients on the income-interaction terms, ρ1 and ρ2,<br />

measure whether low-income consumers are more or less sensitive to changes in the two tax types.<br />

Our primary question is whether <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to the sales tax varies by income. In answering this<br />

question, one must distinguish between <strong>at</strong>tentiveness – the extent to which consumers account for a<br />

tax when making their consumption decisions – and price-sensitivity – which describes how a tax th<strong>at</strong><br />

consumers account for affects their optimal purchase. The sales*low-income interaction term (ρ2) may<br />

reflect differences in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness between high- and low-income consumers, but it may also reflect<br />

19 In addition to the main effect for low-income st<strong>at</strong>us, the individual demographics vector z also includes a continuous<br />

measure of income.<br />

17<br />

(9)


differences in price-sensitivity by income. Th<strong>at</strong> is, a neg<strong>at</strong>ive coefficient on ρ2 could stem from high-<br />

income smokers being less sensitive to cigarette prices in any form, even if high- and low-income smokers<br />

were equally <strong>at</strong>tentive to the sales tax.<br />

To deal with this possibility, it is useful to introduce the notion of the “<strong>at</strong>tention gap,” the amount by<br />

which a consumer’s responsiveness to the excise tax exceeds her responsiveness to the sales tax. For high-<br />

income consumers, the estim<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong>tention gap is simply β2 −β1. In turn, for low-income consumers, the<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>ed <strong>at</strong>tention gap is given by (β2 + ρ2) − (β1 + ρ1). Recall th<strong>at</strong> the neoclassical model described<br />

above predicts th<strong>at</strong> consumers should respond identically to excise and sales taxes th<strong>at</strong> they take into<br />

account. Consequently, we interpret a non-zero value of the <strong>at</strong>tention gap as evidence th<strong>at</strong> consumers<br />

account for one type of tax more than the other.<br />

Although the sign and magnitude of the <strong>at</strong>tention gap for a particular income group are interesting in<br />

their own right, more relevant to our analysis are changes in the <strong>at</strong>tention gap by income. Th<strong>at</strong> is, we<br />

are less concerned with whether a particular group of consumers pays more <strong>at</strong>tention to the excise tax<br />

rel<strong>at</strong>ive to the sales tax, and more concerned with whether low-income consumers pay more <strong>at</strong>tention<br />

to the sales tax (rel<strong>at</strong>ive to the excise tax) than high-income consumers do. 20 It is easy to see th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

estim<strong>at</strong>ed difference in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness between high- and low-income consumers is given by:<br />

∆AttentionGap = [(β2 + ρ2) − (β1 + ρ1)] − [β2 − β1]<br />

= ρ2 − ρ1 (10)<br />

Intuitively, the sales*low-income coefficient (ρ2) reflects changing responsiveness to the sales tax by<br />

income, and the excise*low-income coefficient (ρ1) removes the portion of th<strong>at</strong> change due to changes in<br />

consumers’ price sensitivity. Hence, the gap between the coefficients on the two interaction terms r<strong>at</strong>es,<br />

ρ2 − ρ1, measures the extent to which <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to the register tax changes as income rises. When<br />

ρ2 − ρ1 < 0, high-income consumers pay less <strong>at</strong>tention to the sales tax (rel<strong>at</strong>ive to the excise tax) than<br />

low-income consumers do.<br />

20 After all, it is the differences in behavior between high- and low-income consumers th<strong>at</strong> shapes the distribution of a tax’s<br />

burden.<br />

18


Table IV presents our results. Columns 1 and 4 include the two tax r<strong>at</strong>es, on their own and interacted<br />

with income. In addition, the regressions include demographic variables as well as st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and<br />

month fixed-effects. As before, Columns 2 and 5 add real st<strong>at</strong>e income and the st<strong>at</strong>e unemployment<br />

r<strong>at</strong>e, and Columns 3 and 6 include an interaction between income and a linear time trend to capture the<br />

changing rel<strong>at</strong>ionship between income and smoking behavior over time. The estim<strong>at</strong>ed coefficients on<br />

the demographic and macroeconomic variables are qualit<strong>at</strong>ively similar to those reported in Table II, and<br />

are omitted. Table V combines the intensive and extensive margin estim<strong>at</strong>es into an overall effect, using<br />

the method described in Section II.B. 21<br />

The results in Tables IV and V support the view th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes declines with<br />

income. As before, Columns 3 and 6 are our preferred specific<strong>at</strong>ion. 22 On both the intensive and extensive<br />

margins, the estim<strong>at</strong>ed tax coefficients suggest th<strong>at</strong> high-income consumers are less responsive to the<br />

sales tax than to the excise tax: the excise tax coefficients are neg<strong>at</strong>ive and significantly different from<br />

zero, whereas the sales tax coefficients are small in magnitude and st<strong>at</strong>istically insignificant. 23<br />

For low-income consumers, the results paint a dram<strong>at</strong>ically different picture. The coefficient on the<br />

interaction between low-income st<strong>at</strong>us and the sales tax and is neg<strong>at</strong>ive and significant, implying th<strong>at</strong> an<br />

increase in the sale tax is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with a larger reduction in demand for low-income consumers than<br />

for high-income consumers. The small coefficient on the excise*low-income interaction term suggests<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the result reflects a difference in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness r<strong>at</strong>her than a mere difference in price-sensitivity by<br />

income.<br />

Recall from (10) th<strong>at</strong> changes in the <strong>at</strong>tention gap by income are captured by ρ2 − ρ1. Hence, to<br />

investig<strong>at</strong>e whether low-income consumers are particularly <strong>at</strong>tentive to register taxes, we test whether<br />

ρ1 = ρ2. The associ<strong>at</strong>ed F-tests are reported in Tables IV and V. Under our preferred specific<strong>at</strong>ions, the<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong>istics for the intensive and extensive margin are 5.24 and 3.13, respectively. Hence, our results are<br />

consistent with the hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> low-income consumers pay more <strong>at</strong>tention to cigarette register taxes<br />

than do high-income consumers. 24<br />

21The robustness checks th<strong>at</strong> follow use the specific<strong>at</strong>ion in Columns 3 and 6 as their baseline.<br />

22The only qualit<strong>at</strong>ive difference between specific<strong>at</strong>ions is the coefficient on the excise*low-income interaction, which<br />

declines sharply in magnitude once the income time trend is added to the model.<br />

23However, as in the general popul<strong>at</strong>ion regression, the F-tests for equality between the two high-income tax coefficients<br />

are inconclusive.<br />

24One interesting result is th<strong>at</strong> on both margins, the implied effect of the sales tax is estim<strong>at</strong>ed to be gre<strong>at</strong>er in magnitude<br />

19


So far, we have divided the analysis into low-income consumers on the one hand (those below the 25th<br />

percentile in income) and medium- to high-income consumers on the other. Although th<strong>at</strong> aggreg<strong>at</strong>ion is<br />

convenient for exposition, it may mask differences in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness between medium- and high-income<br />

consumers. The regressions in Table VI introduce additional flexibility into the model by allowing con-<br />

sumers in each income quartile to respond to the taxes in different ways. The resulting specific<strong>at</strong>ion is<br />

given by<br />

yismt = α + β1τ e smt + β2τ s smt + ∑<br />

j∈{II,III,IV }<br />

<br />

η j Q j j<br />

ismt + ρ1τe smtQ j j<br />

ismt + ρ2τs smtQ j<br />

<br />

ismt +<br />

γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + πm + εismt<br />

where Q j<br />

ismt indic<strong>at</strong>es whether consumer i falls into income quartile j.<br />

As before, we find th<strong>at</strong> income differences in how consumers respond to the excise tax tend to be<br />

small and st<strong>at</strong>istically insignificant. In contrast, responsiveness to the sales tax declines monotonically<br />

with income. F-tests for the equality of the <strong>at</strong>tention gap between consumers in different income quartiles<br />

are reported in Table VI as well. The results suggest th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to cigarette register taxes declines<br />

monotonically by income. 25<br />

than the implied effect of the excise tax for low-income consumers, although the difference is only significant on the extensive<br />

margin. This result could stem from differences in the goods included in the excise and sales tax bases, a possibility explored<br />

in Section II.D. Of course, it is also possible th<strong>at</strong> the estim<strong>at</strong>ed sales tax coefficient is biased downward due to some omitted<br />

variable. However, unless th<strong>at</strong> omitted variable was differentialy correl<strong>at</strong>ed with smoking demand by high- and low-income<br />

consumers, it would not drive the differences in sales tax responsiveness th<strong>at</strong> we observe. The fact th<strong>at</strong> the income differences<br />

in sales tax responsiveness do not appear in st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> exempt cigarettes from the sales tax lends confidence th<strong>at</strong> omitted<br />

variables are not driving our main result (see Table VII).<br />

25 An implicit assumption in our analysis (and throughout the smoking liter<strong>at</strong>ure) is th<strong>at</strong> changes in cigarette taxes are<br />

uncorrel<strong>at</strong>ed with unobserved shocks to individuals’ cigarette consumption. However, cigarette taxes are not set randomly; a<br />

positive shock to cigarette demand might prompt st<strong>at</strong>e legisl<strong>at</strong>ors to raise excise taxes to capture additional revenue. Although<br />

such correl<strong>at</strong>ions could provide an altern<strong>at</strong>ive explan<strong>at</strong>ion for the discrepancy between the excise and sales tax coefficients<br />

in Section II.B, it is more difficult to imagine them driving the heterogeneous <strong>at</strong>tentiveness results in Section II.C. Th<strong>at</strong> is,<br />

although there are many possible reasons for cigarette taxes to be correl<strong>at</strong>ed with unobserved shocks to smoking demand,<br />

there are fewer plausible reasons why adoption of such laws would be differently correl<strong>at</strong>ed with shocks to cigarette demand<br />

for high and low-income consumers. Moreover, to the extent th<strong>at</strong> policymakers do consider cigarette demand by high- and<br />

low-income consumers differently when setting tax r<strong>at</strong>es, it would be surprising if they took such behavior into account when<br />

setting the sales tax (for which cigarette sales constitute only a small fraction of total revenue). So although it appears unlikely<br />

th<strong>at</strong> the endogenous adoption of tax laws is driving our main results, we cannot rule th<strong>at</strong> possibility out definitively.<br />

20<br />

(11)


D. Tax Base Differences Between the Excise and Sales Tax<br />

Our str<strong>at</strong>egy for measuring <strong>at</strong>tentiveness has been to compare consumer responsiveness to excise and<br />

sales tax r<strong>at</strong>es. When demand for cigarettes depends only on the price of cigarettes and income, any<br />

gap between how consumers respond to the sales tax and how they respond to the excise tax implies<br />

a departure from the neoclassical model (as explained in Section II.B). In reality, the price of goods<br />

other than cigarettes may enter the cigarette demand function as well; if some of those other goods are<br />

also covered by the sales tax, the effect of a sales tax increase on cigarette demand will differ from the<br />

effect of an excise tax increase. This observ<strong>at</strong>ion complic<strong>at</strong>es our analysis because income differences in<br />

the <strong>at</strong>tention gap may be due to differences in the excise and sales tax bases, r<strong>at</strong>her than differences in<br />

<strong>at</strong>tentiveness.<br />

To clarify the n<strong>at</strong>ure of the problem, it will be helpful to discuss this tax-base effect in some detail.<br />

Under the neoclassical model, a tax can affect cigarette demand in two ways: by raising the price of<br />

cigarettes (a direct effect), and by raising the price of other goods (an indirect effect). Because the<br />

excise tax applies only to cigarettes, it gener<strong>at</strong>es only a direct effect. In contrast, the sales tax applies<br />

to many goods, 26 and consequently, it gener<strong>at</strong>es both a direct effect and an indirect effect on cigarette<br />

consumption. As a result, income differences in the <strong>at</strong>tention gap could reflect both income differences<br />

in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness as well as income differences in the n<strong>at</strong>ure of the sales tax’s indirect effect. In particular,<br />

if the indirect effect of the sales tax on cigarette demand were more neg<strong>at</strong>ive for low-income consumers<br />

than for high-income ones, it could be th<strong>at</strong> a tax base effect r<strong>at</strong>her than changing <strong>at</strong>tentiveness is driving<br />

our results. Th<strong>at</strong> is, low-income consumers’ gre<strong>at</strong>er responsiveness to the sales tax could stem from<br />

income differences in how consumers adjust cigarette demand in response to price changes on other<br />

sales-taxed good.<br />

Might income differences in the indirect effect of the sales tax be driving our results? It is difficult<br />

to dismiss this possibility out of hand. The indirect effect of the sales tax can be decomposed into<br />

an income effect and a substitution effect. By raising the price of many goods <strong>at</strong> once, the sales tax<br />

diminishes consumers’ purchasing power, causing them to reduce their consumption of cigarettes (the<br />

income effect). In addition, raising the price of other goods might cause consumers to substitute toward<br />

26 Approxim<strong>at</strong>ely 40 percent of retail sales, according to CLK.<br />

21


or away from cigarettes, depending on whether the other goods covered by the sales tax are primarily<br />

substitutes or complements to cigarettes (the substitution effect). In theory, either of these effects could<br />

be more neg<strong>at</strong>ive for low-income consumers. For example, the other sales-taxed goods could be important<br />

substitutes with cigarettes for well-off consumers, but not for low-income consumers. Similarly, the loss<br />

in real income associ<strong>at</strong>ed with a sales tax increase could induce a bigger reduction in cigarette demand<br />

for low-income consumers.<br />

We present two pieces of evidence th<strong>at</strong> tax base effects are not responsible for all of the observed<br />

differences in consumer behavior by income. Our first check is motiv<strong>at</strong>ed by the fact th<strong>at</strong> some st<strong>at</strong>es<br />

impose a general sales tax, but exempt cigarettes from it. 27 In st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> exempt cigarettes from the sales<br />

tax, changes in the sales tax r<strong>at</strong>e would not directly affect the price of cigarettes; the sales tax would not<br />

have a direct effect on cigarette consumption. However, sales tax changes would still affect the price of<br />

other sales tax-eligible goods. Hence, the indirect effect of the sales tax would still occur. Consequently,<br />

analyzing the effect of the sales tax in cigarette-exempting st<strong>at</strong>es allows us to measure income differences<br />

in the indirect effect of the sales tax.<br />

If indirect effects were responsible for the observed differences in responsiveness to the sales tax by<br />

income, responsive to the sales tax should decline by income, even in st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> exempted cigarettes.<br />

Table VII compares the effect of the sales tax in st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> exempt cigarettes from the sales tax (“exempt<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es”) with the effect of the sales tax in st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> include cigarettes in the sales tax base (“non-exempt<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es”). To do so, we modify our econometric model to allow heterogeneity in the effect of the sales tax<br />

between exempt and non-exempt st<strong>at</strong>es:<br />

yismt = α + β1τ e smt + β2τ s smt ∗ Es + β3τ s smt ∗ (1 − Est) +<br />

ρ1τ e smtLIismt + ρ2τ s smtLIismt ∗ Es + ρ3τ s smtLIismt ∗ (1 − Est) +<br />

φEst + ϕEst ∗t + ηLIismt + γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + πm + εismt<br />

where Es indic<strong>at</strong>es whether st<strong>at</strong>e s exempts cigarettes from the sales tax base.<br />

Table VII shows th<strong>at</strong> the effect of the sales tax on cigarette demand appears to vary substantially<br />

27 In our sample, seven st<strong>at</strong>es exempt cigarettes from the sales tax base for <strong>at</strong> least one year.<br />

22<br />

(12)


more by income in non-exempt st<strong>at</strong>es than in exempt st<strong>at</strong>es. The estim<strong>at</strong>ed sales*low-income coefficient<br />

in exempt st<strong>at</strong>es, ρ2, is close to zero and is st<strong>at</strong>istically insignificant on both the intensive and extensive<br />

margins. In contrast, the sales*low-income coefficient in the non-exempt st<strong>at</strong>es, ρ3, remains large and<br />

significant. Moreover, on the extensive margin, we are able to reject the hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> the sales*low-<br />

income coefficient in the exempt st<strong>at</strong>es is as large as in the non-exempt st<strong>at</strong>es. These findings suggest<br />

th<strong>at</strong> income differences in indirect effects are not driving the results in Section II.C.<br />

We also present a second check th<strong>at</strong> tax base effects are not driving our results. Tax base effects are<br />

most likely to dampen the impact of the sales tax rel<strong>at</strong>ive to the excise tax when the excise tax exempts<br />

important substitutes for cigarettes. 28 Because other tobacco products constitute likely substitutes for<br />

cigarettes, there is less potential for tax base differences to play a role in st<strong>at</strong>es where the excise tax<br />

also applies to other tobacco products. Consequently, we restrict the analysis in Section II.C to st<strong>at</strong>es<br />

th<strong>at</strong> apply the excise tax to cigars and smokeless tobacco. Table VIII shows th<strong>at</strong> our results are largely<br />

unchanged by this restriction.<br />

In summary, there are plausible reasons to believe th<strong>at</strong> differences in the excise and sales tax bases<br />

could gener<strong>at</strong>e results similar to those presented in Section II.C. However, the evidence in Tables VII<br />

and VIII suggests th<strong>at</strong> tax base effects cannot fully supplant <strong>at</strong>tentiveness as an explan<strong>at</strong>ion for the large<br />

differences in behavior th<strong>at</strong> we find between high- and low-income consumers.<br />

E. Robustness Checks<br />

1. Including Pre-Tax Prices in the Regression<br />

One variable not included in our basic econometric model is the pre-tax price of cigarettes. On the one<br />

hand, the pre-tax price depends on both supply and demand; including it as a regressor could bias our re-<br />

sults if it were correl<strong>at</strong>ed with unobserved shocks to consumer demand (the classic simultaneous systems<br />

problem). On the other hand, the pre-tax price enters the consumer’s demand function symmetrically<br />

with the excise and sales tax r<strong>at</strong>es; excluding it from the regression may cre<strong>at</strong>e an omitted variable bias<br />

28 For example, raising the excise tax might reduce cigarette demand substantially by inducing cigarette smokers to switch<br />

to cigars. In contrast, raising the sales tax would raise the price of both cigarettes and cigars, dampening the effect on cigarette<br />

consumption.<br />

23


if pre-tax price fluctu<strong>at</strong>ions were not equally correl<strong>at</strong>ed with the two tax types. 29<br />

In this section, we modify our empirical str<strong>at</strong>egy to account for the pre-tax price of cigarettes.<br />

Whereas previously we compared sales tax changes to excise tax changes, we now compare sales tax<br />

changes to changes in the posted price of cigarettes (the pre-tax price plus the excise tax). As before,<br />

this approach isol<strong>at</strong>es income differences in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness r<strong>at</strong>her than changing price-sensitivity. The<br />

econometric model takes the following form:<br />

yismt = α + β1ppsmt + β2τ s smt + ρ1ppsmtLIismt + ρ2τ s smtLIismt + γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + πm + εismt (13)<br />

where pp represents the (excise tax inclusive) log posted price of cigarettes. To address the possible<br />

correl<strong>at</strong>ion between pre-tax prices and unobserved demand shocks, we utilize the excise tax as a supply<br />

shifter. In particular, we employ the excise tax (τ e ) and the excise*low-income interaction (τ e ∗ LI )<br />

as instruments for the posted price (pp) and the posted price*low-income interaction (pp ∗ LI). This<br />

identific<strong>at</strong>ion str<strong>at</strong>egy is valid under the same assumptions as the main specific<strong>at</strong>ion, namely th<strong>at</strong> cigarette<br />

tax changes are uncorrel<strong>at</strong>ed with unobserved shocks to cigarette demand. Tables IX and X show th<strong>at</strong> the<br />

results from the IV specific<strong>at</strong>ion are similar to the specific<strong>at</strong>ions th<strong>at</strong> omit pre-tax prices.<br />

2. Altern<strong>at</strong>ive Demand Models<br />

So far, we have followed the approach taken by much of the smoking liter<strong>at</strong>ure by separ<strong>at</strong>ely modeling the<br />

extensive and intensive margins of cigarette consumption. This approach has the advantage of providing<br />

inform<strong>at</strong>ion about the mechanism by which tax changes reduce cigarette demand, in particular whether<br />

higher prices reduce demand by motiv<strong>at</strong>ing smokers to quit or cut back. However, a drawback of this<br />

approach is th<strong>at</strong> the intensive margin results may be biased by changes to the composition of the smoking<br />

popul<strong>at</strong>ion. 30<br />

As a robustness check, we estim<strong>at</strong>e smoking demand using a linear regression and a Tobit model<br />

censored <strong>at</strong> zero. The dependent variable in these regressions is the number of cigarettes smoked per day,<br />

29For example, Harding, Leitbag and Lovenheim (2010) find th<strong>at</strong> excise taxes are passed through differently to high- and<br />

low-income consumers.<br />

30For example, suppose th<strong>at</strong> smokers’ demand for cigarettes were completely insensitive to price changes, but th<strong>at</strong> light<br />

smokers quit when the price became too high. In such a world, a tax increase would appear to raise the intensity of smoking<br />

demand on the intensive margin merely by raising the fraction of heavy smokers in the smoking popul<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

24


with the variable assigned a value of zero when the individual in question is not a smoker. Because the<br />

entire popul<strong>at</strong>ion of respondents is used, these approaches avoid the problem th<strong>at</strong> tax r<strong>at</strong>e changes affect<br />

selection into the smoking popul<strong>at</strong>ion. The flip side of the coin is th<strong>at</strong> these models do not allow variables<br />

to differ in how they affect smoking demand on the intensive and extensive margins. Moreover, the Tobit<br />

specific<strong>at</strong>ion relies on the normality of the unobservables and the linear functional form is probably<br />

unrealistic for an applic<strong>at</strong>ion in which so many of the observ<strong>at</strong>ions have a dependent variable equal to<br />

zero. The results of the linear and Tobit specific<strong>at</strong>ions are presented in Table XI and are consistent with<br />

the results from the two-part model used in the rest of the paper.<br />

3. Delayed Responses to Tax Changes<br />

So far we have assumed th<strong>at</strong> smoking demand depends only upon current cigarette taxes, but it could be<br />

th<strong>at</strong> tax changes affect consumer behavior with a lag. For example, higher prices might motiv<strong>at</strong>e smokers<br />

to quit, but the quitting process itself could take several months. Altern<strong>at</strong>ively, it could be th<strong>at</strong> consumers<br />

take some time to learn about sales tax changes, only gradually incorpor<strong>at</strong>ing them into their behavior. If<br />

these lags were different for high- and low-income consumers, it could provide an altern<strong>at</strong>ive explan<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

for our results. 31 To investig<strong>at</strong>e this issue, we examine the sensitivity of our results to using various lags<br />

of the tax r<strong>at</strong>es instead of the current r<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

yismt = α + β1τ e sm,t−k + β2τ s sm,t−k + ρ1τ e sm,t−k LIismt + ρ2τ s sm,t−k LIismt + ηLIismt +<br />

γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + πm + εismt<br />

where k, is three, six, or twelve months. The results are reported in Table XII and suggest th<strong>at</strong> our results<br />

are not being driven by differences in the time it takes high- and low-income consumers to respond to<br />

cigarette tax changes.<br />

31 For example, high-income consumers may be better able to afford top of the line smoking-cess<strong>at</strong>ion products.<br />

25<br />

(14)


4. St<strong>at</strong>e Specific Trends<br />

Although including st<strong>at</strong>e fixed-effects accounts for unobserved factors th<strong>at</strong> affect the levels of smoking<br />

demand by st<strong>at</strong>e, it could be th<strong>at</strong> changes in a st<strong>at</strong>e’s tax r<strong>at</strong>es are correl<strong>at</strong>ed with trends in th<strong>at</strong> st<strong>at</strong>e’s<br />

cigarette demand, such as anti-smoking sentiment. To reduce the influence of any such omitted third<br />

factors, we add st<strong>at</strong>e-specific year trends to the econometric model. 32 Table XIII shows th<strong>at</strong> the estim<strong>at</strong>ed<br />

coefficients are largely unchanged by this addition.<br />

III. Conclusion<br />

yismt = α + β1τ e smt + β2τ s smt + ρ1τ e smtLIismt + ρ2τ s smtLIismt + ηLIismt +<br />

γxsmt + δzismt + µs + λt + ξs ∗t + πm + εismt<br />

Policymakers <strong>at</strong> all levels of government depend on commodity taxes to raise revenue, but such taxes are<br />

typically regressive, constituting a gre<strong>at</strong>er burden for low-income consumers. This paper has suggested a<br />

novel way for policymakers to lessen th<strong>at</strong> regressivity: manipul<strong>at</strong>ing the fraction of the tax th<strong>at</strong> is levied<br />

<strong>at</strong> the register as opposed to being included in a good’s posted price. In particular, we showed th<strong>at</strong> levying<br />

a gre<strong>at</strong>er proportion of a commodity tax <strong>at</strong> the register shifts the tax’s burden away from <strong>at</strong>tentive con-<br />

sumers. When low-income consumers pay more <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes than high-income consumers<br />

do, designing a tax in this way can lessen its regressivity. Conversely, when high-income consumers are<br />

the more <strong>at</strong>tentive, imposing a commodity tax <strong>at</strong> the register will exacerb<strong>at</strong>e its regressivity.<br />

With this motiv<strong>at</strong>ion in mind, we investig<strong>at</strong>ed whether high- and low-income consumers respond<br />

differently to register taxes on cigarettes. Exploiting st<strong>at</strong>e and time vari<strong>at</strong>ion in tax r<strong>at</strong>es, we found<br />

th<strong>at</strong> low-income consumers respond to both excise and sales taxes on cigarettes, whereas higher-income<br />

consumers only respond to excise taxes. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness<br />

32 Although our tax r<strong>at</strong>e d<strong>at</strong>a is probably largely free of measurement error, including st<strong>at</strong>e trends could still cause substantial<br />

<strong>at</strong>tenu<strong>at</strong>ion bias in the current context. Suppose th<strong>at</strong> smoking demand depends upon a function of current and past tax r<strong>at</strong>es,<br />

xt = x(a(L)xt), where a(L) is some lag polynomial. The situ<strong>at</strong>ion here is analagous to the standard measurement error problem:<br />

although the original tax variable xt may be highly correl<strong>at</strong>ed with the “true” tax variable a(L)xt, the new tax measure after<br />

including st<strong>at</strong>e trends may only be weakly correl<strong>at</strong>ed with the “true” tax r<strong>at</strong>e, causing an <strong>at</strong>tenu<strong>at</strong>ion bias.<br />

26<br />

(15)


to cigarette register taxes declines by income. Hence, policymakers may be able to ease the financial<br />

burden of cigarette taxes on the poor by levying such taxes <strong>at</strong> the register instead of including them in<br />

cigarettes’ posted price.<br />

Two qualific<strong>at</strong>ions are important when interpreting this result. First, we have tre<strong>at</strong>ed cigarettes as<br />

a standard consumption good, abstracting away from their addictive n<strong>at</strong>ure. However, the fact th<strong>at</strong><br />

cigarettes are addictive could alter the welfare implic<strong>at</strong>ions of our results. For example, models along the<br />

lines suggested by Jon<strong>at</strong>han Gruber and Botond Koszegi (2004) or Jon<strong>at</strong>han Gruber and Sendhil Mul-<br />

lain<strong>at</strong>han (2002) suggest th<strong>at</strong> cigarette taxes can benefit consumer welfare when voters adopt such taxes<br />

as a method of exercising self-control; consequently, shifting a cigarette tax to the register could deprive<br />

some consumers of a valuable tool for self-discipline. At the other extreme, a r<strong>at</strong>ional-addiction model<br />

such as th<strong>at</strong> presented in Gary S. Becker, Michael Grossman, and Kevin M. Murphy (1994) would imply<br />

th<strong>at</strong> cigarette consumption decisions are informed by consumers’ expect<strong>at</strong>ions concerning future prices;<br />

if such expect<strong>at</strong>ions are important, the demand equ<strong>at</strong>ions employed here are misspecified.<br />

Second, readers should be cautious about extrapol<strong>at</strong>ing our results to goods other than cigarettes.<br />

Although we believe th<strong>at</strong> there are strong theoretical and empirical reasons to think th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to<br />

cigarette register taxes declines by income, the cognitive cost model presented in Appendix C highlights<br />

the fact th<strong>at</strong> this result can vary between goods. In particular, low-income consumers may well be less<br />

<strong>at</strong>tentive to register taxes on goods th<strong>at</strong> are rel<strong>at</strong>ively sensitive to income and th<strong>at</strong> constitute a larger share<br />

of expenditures for high-income consumers. Moreover, Appendix B shows th<strong>at</strong> shifting to a register tax<br />

has the potential to make consumers worse off by inducing producers to raise a good’s pre-tax price. For<br />

goods whose markets are characterized by elastic demand and inelastic supply, shifting to a register tax<br />

could actually worsen the burden of those taxes on the poor.<br />

Although our discussion has focused on taxes designed to raise revenue, the empirical findings pre-<br />

sented here also speak to broader questions of tax design. For example, a number of public health<br />

advoc<strong>at</strong>es have suggested raising taxes on soft drinks as a way to comb<strong>at</strong> popul<strong>at</strong>ion obesity, with some<br />

proponents calling for an expanded tax of any form on those products (Carolyn L. Engelhard, Arthur<br />

Garson Jr., and Stan Dorn (2009)) and others arguing th<strong>at</strong> including the tax in the posted product price<br />

would be most effective (Kelly D. Brownell et al. (2009)). Our results suggest an important consider<strong>at</strong>ion<br />

27


is missing from this discussion, namely th<strong>at</strong> taxes imposed <strong>at</strong> the register may affect the e<strong>at</strong>ing habits of<br />

high- and low-income consumers in different ways. Such issues deserve further investig<strong>at</strong>ion.<br />

28


References<br />

[1] Becker, Gary, Michael Grossman, and Kevin Murphy, “An Empirical Analysis of Cigarette Addic-<br />

tion,” American Economic Review, 84 (1994), 396-418.<br />

[2] Bertrand, Marianne, Sendhil Mullain<strong>at</strong>han, and Eldar Shafir, “A Behavioral-Economics View of<br />

Poverty,” American Economics Review Papers and Proceedings, 94 (2004), 419-423.<br />

[3] Brownell, Kelly D., Thomas Farley, Walter C. Willett, Barry M. Popkin, Frank J. Chaloupka, Joseph<br />

W. Thompson, and David S. Ludwig, “The Public Health and Economic Benefits of Taxing Sugar-<br />

sweetened Beverages,” New England Journal of Medicine, 361 (2009), 1599–605.<br />

[4] Cabral, Marika, and Caroline Hoxby, “The H<strong>at</strong>ed Property Tax: Salience, Tax R<strong>at</strong>es, and Tax Re-<br />

volts,” Unpublished.<br />

[5] Chaloupka, Frank J. and Kenneth Warner, "The Economics of Smoking," In Handbook of Health<br />

Economics, Anthony Culyer and Joseph Newhouse, ed., 1539 -1628 (Amsterdam: North-Holland,<br />

2000).<br />

[6] Chetty, Raj, Adam Looney and Kory Kroft, “Salience and Tax<strong>at</strong>ion: Theory and Evidence,” Ameri-<br />

can Economic Review, 99 (2009), 1145-1177.<br />

[7] Chetty, Raj, Adam Looney, and Kory Kroft, “Salience and Tax<strong>at</strong>ion: Theory and Evidence,” NBER<br />

Working Paper No. w13330, 2007.<br />

[8] Engelhard, Carolyn, Arthur Garson, and Stan Dorn, “Reducing Obesity: Policy Str<strong>at</strong>egies from the<br />

Tobacco Wars,” (Washington (DC): Urban Institute, 2009).<br />

[9] Finkelstein, Amy, “E-Z Tax: Tax Salience and Tax R<strong>at</strong>es,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124<br />

(2009), 969-1010.<br />

[10] Gruber, Jon<strong>at</strong>han, and Botond Koszegi, “Tax Incidence When Individuals are Time-inconsistent:<br />

The Case of Cigarette Excise Taxes,” Journal of Public Economics, 88 (2004), 1959-1987.<br />

[11] Gruber, Jon<strong>at</strong>han, and Sendhil Mullain<strong>at</strong>han, “Do Cigarette Taxes Make Smokers Happier?,” NBER<br />

Working Paper No. w8872, 2002.<br />

[12] Hall, Crystal, “Mental Accounting in the Context of Poverty,” Unpublished, 2010.<br />

[18] Harding, Leitbag and Lovenheim, “The Heterogenous Geographic and Socieconomic Incidence of<br />

Cigarette Taxes: Evidence from Nielson Homescan D<strong>at</strong>a,” Working Paper (2010).<br />

29


[13] McDonald, John F., and Robert A. Moffitt, “The Uses of Tobit Analysis,” Review of Economics<br />

and St<strong>at</strong>istics, 62 (1980), 318–21.<br />

[14] Mullain<strong>at</strong>han, Sendhil and Eldar Shafir, “Savings Policy & Decision-Making in Low-Income<br />

Households,” In Insufficient Funds: Savings, Assets, Credit and Banking Among Low-Income<br />

Households, Michael Barr and Rebecca Blank, ed. (New York: Russell Sage Found<strong>at</strong>ion, 2009).<br />

[15] Orzechowski and Walker, “The Tax Burden on Tobacco,” (Arlington, Virginia: Orzechowski and<br />

Walker, 2008).<br />

[16] Slemrod, Joel and Wojciech Kopczuk, “The Optimal Elasticity of Taxable Income,” Journal of<br />

Public Economics, 84 (2002), 91-112.<br />

[17] Shue, Kelly and Erzo F. P. Luttmer, “Who Misvotes? The Effect of Differential Cognition Costs on<br />

Election Outcomes,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1 (2009), 229-257.<br />

30


Appendix A: Welfare Analysis Under Altern<strong>at</strong>e Budget Adjustment Rules<br />

Part I assumed th<strong>at</strong> in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers who misperceive the price of x s<strong>at</strong>isfy their budget con-<br />

straints by reducing expenditures on y. This Appendix considers the robustness of our results to altern<strong>at</strong>e<br />

rules for mapping infeasible intended consumption bundles into feasible final consumption bundles.<br />

In addition to the rule th<strong>at</strong> we employ, Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) identify two other “intuitive”<br />

budget adjustment rules. First, consumers who misperceive the price of x may s<strong>at</strong>isfy their budget con-<br />

straints by reducing expenditures on x r<strong>at</strong>her than y. This rule represents the other end of the spectrum<br />

from the one th<strong>at</strong> we employ, and would be appropri<strong>at</strong>e if consumers purchased x after completing their<br />

purchases of all other goods. Under this rule, it is easy to show th<strong>at</strong>:<br />

∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

∂xB<br />

=<br />

∂tp<br />

= −xB<br />

p +tr +tp<br />

<br />

∂yB − ∂ p + xB<br />

p +tr +tp<br />

The second altern<strong>at</strong>e budget adjustment considered by Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007) is for in<strong>at</strong>-<br />

tentive agents to reduce consumption of both x and y to make up the income lost to the register tax.<br />

In<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers ignore the register tax when making their consumption decisions, but recognize<br />

th<strong>at</strong> their net-of-tax income is lower because of the tax. For example, consumers who purchase x and y<br />

repe<strong>at</strong>edly will eventually realize th<strong>at</strong> they consistently have less money in their bank account than they<br />

had anticip<strong>at</strong>ed. In<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers whose behavior is described by this rule will fully account for the<br />

tax’s income effect but fail to account for the tax’s substitution effect. As a result, we have:<br />

where<br />

∂ ˜<br />

xB<br />

∂ p<br />

∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

∂xB<br />

∂tp<br />

∂xB<br />

= −xB<br />

∂I<br />

= ∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

represents Hicksian (compens<strong>at</strong>ed) demand.<br />

As before, we consider the welfare effects of a revenue-neutral shift from posted to register taxes.<br />

31<br />

+ ∂ ˜xB<br />

∂ p<br />

(16)<br />

(17)<br />

(18)<br />

(19)


Because the <strong>at</strong>tentive agent optimizes correctly, the welfare effect for th<strong>at</strong> agent is the same as before:<br />

<br />

dVA <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

<br />

= −Uy (xA,yA)xA 1 + ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

Totally differenti<strong>at</strong>ing the government’s budget constraint yields an expression for the posted tax<br />

reduction associ<strong>at</strong>ed with a revenue-neutral increase in the register tax:<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

= − xA + xB + (tp +tr)( ∂xA<br />

∂tr<br />

xA + xB + (tp +tr)( ∂xA<br />

∂tp<br />

R<br />

+ ∂xB<br />

∂tr )<br />

+ ∂xB<br />

∂tp )<br />

A little algebra reveals th<strong>at</strong> the welfare effect of the shift is positive for <strong>at</strong>tentive consumers if and<br />

only if ∂xB<br />

∂tr<br />

∂xB > , th<strong>at</strong> is, when in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers reduce their demand for the taxed good by a larger<br />

∂tp<br />

amount in response to a posted tax increase than in response to a register tax increase. Intuitively, this<br />

condition ensures th<strong>at</strong> the new register tax will be more effective <strong>at</strong> raising revenue than the old posted<br />

tax was. Consequently, the shift accomod<strong>at</strong>es a reduction in the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e, thus gener<strong>at</strong>ing a<br />

positive income effect. Using (16) - (19), it is easy to see th<strong>at</strong> this condition is s<strong>at</strong>isfied under the two<br />

altern<strong>at</strong>e budget adjustment rules. 33<br />

The welfare analysis for in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers proceeds as in Part I. Under the first altern<strong>at</strong>e rule,<br />

<br />

dVB <br />

= − 1 + dtr R ∂tp<br />

<br />

∂yB ∂tp <br />

<br />

xB<br />

∂ p ∂tr<br />

<br />

R<br />

Ux(xB,yB) +<br />

∂tr<br />

p+tr+tp (p+tr+tp) (Uy(xA,yA)(p +tr +tp) −Ux(xA,yA))<br />

R<br />

Like the result in Part I, the welfare effect for in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers is ambiguous under this rule.<br />

Shifting to a register tax accomod<strong>at</strong>es a reduction in the combined tax r<strong>at</strong>e, gener<strong>at</strong>ing a positive welfare<br />

effect (captured by the first term). Unlike before, however, the magnitude of this effect depends on the<br />

marginal utility of x r<strong>at</strong>her than y because providing the consumer with additional income reduces the<br />

amount th<strong>at</strong> the consumer must reduce her consumption of x to s<strong>at</strong>isfy the budget constraint. The second<br />

term represents the cost of optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error. Like before, this cost is zero when there are no register<br />

taxes and grows in size as register taxes push in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers further from their optimal bundle.<br />

Under the second altern<strong>at</strong>e rule, the welfare effect of the shift for in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers is also similar<br />

to th<strong>at</strong> found in Part I. Here the welfare effect is given by<br />

<br />

<br />

= − 1 +<br />

R ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

Uy(xB,yB)xB + − xB<br />

R ∂xB<br />

<br />

(Ux(xB,yB) − (p +tr +tp)Uy(xB,yB))<br />

dVB<br />

dtr<br />

∂tr R<br />

∂xB<br />

∂ p<br />

33 Because y represents all goods other than x, we assume th<strong>at</strong> ∂yB<br />

∂ p<br />

∂tr<br />

32<br />

∂I<br />

> 0.


Again, the first term represents a positive income effect and the second term represents a neg<strong>at</strong>ive<br />

welfare effect stemming from optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error, which grows in size as register taxes increase.<br />

Appendix B: Welfare Analysis under Endogenous Producer Prices<br />

This Appendix expands the model developed in Part I to the setting in which firms adjust their prices<br />

in response to changes in the type of tax imposed. Like before, the policy change we consider is an<br />

increase in the register tax accompanied by a reduction in the posted tax designed to keep government<br />

revenue unchanged.<br />

For the <strong>at</strong>tentive consumer (A), the welfare effect of the shift may be found by differenti<strong>at</strong>ing the<br />

indirect utility function:<br />

<br />

dVa <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

<br />

∂ px <br />

= −Uy(xA,yA)(xA) <br />

∂tr<br />

<br />

R<br />

= −Uy(xA,yA)(xA) 1 + ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

+ ∂ p<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

This equ<strong>at</strong>ion differs from (6) in th<strong>at</strong> it reflects changes in the pre-tax price of x in addition to changes in<br />

the combined tax on x. In words, the welfare effect of the shift for A stems entirely from the change in<br />

<br />

d px <br />

the after-tax price of x, px = p +tp +tr. When the net effect is neg<strong>at</strong>ive, < 0, the resulting income<br />

dtr R<br />

effect makes A better off ( dVa<br />

<br />

<br />

> 0). In turn, when the net effect of the shift is to raise the after-tax price<br />

dtr R<br />

of x, the associ<strong>at</strong>ed income effect reduces A’s welfare.<br />

To solve for ∂tp<br />

<br />

∂ p<br />

and , consider the market clearing condition x(p,tp,tr) = s(p), in which<br />

R R<br />

∂tr<br />

∂tr<br />

aggreg<strong>at</strong>e demand is the sum of demand by <strong>at</strong>tentive and in<strong>at</strong>tentive consumers, x(p,tp,tr) ≡ xa(p +tp +<br />

tr) + xb(p +tp), and s(p) represents producer supply. Totally differenti<strong>at</strong>ing this condition as well as the<br />

government’s budget constraint yields:<br />

<br />

∂ p<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

<br />

∂tp <br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

=<br />

=<br />

∂xb<br />

∂ p<br />

∂x ∂s tr+tp<br />

∂ p − ∂ p − x<br />

∂s ∂x tr+tp<br />

∂ p − ∂ p + x<br />

∂x ∂s tr+tp<br />

∂ p − ∂ p − x<br />

33<br />

<br />

∂x ∂s<br />

∂ p<br />

∂ p<br />

<br />

∂s ∂xA<br />

∂ p ∂ p<br />

<br />

∂X<br />

∂ p<br />

∂s<br />

∂ p


Hence, the net effect of a revenue-neutral shift on the after-tax price of x is given by:<br />

<br />

dpx <br />

<br />

dtr<br />

R<br />

= ∂ p<br />

=<br />

=<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

R<br />

∂xb<br />

∂ p<br />

∂x ∂s<br />

∂ p − ∂ p<br />

∂x<br />

∂ p −<br />

+ ∂tp<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

∂tr<br />

+ 1<br />

R<br />

1 − tr+tp<br />

<br />

∂s<br />

x ∂ p<br />

<br />

tr+tp ∂x ∂s<br />

− x ∂ p ∂ p<br />

<br />

1 − tr+tp<br />

<br />

∂s<br />

x ∂ p<br />

<br />

1 − tr+tp<br />

<br />

x −<br />

∂xb<br />

∂ p<br />

The shift positively affects A’s welfare if and only if<br />

∂x<br />

∂ p<br />

∂xb<br />

∂ p<br />

∂s<br />

∂ p<br />

<br />

∂s<br />

∂ p<br />

<br />

1 − tr+tp<br />

<br />

∂s<br />

x ∂ p<br />

<br />

1 − tr+tp<br />

> 0 (20)<br />

x<br />

∂s<br />

∂ p<br />

− ∂s<br />

∂ p<br />

When will (20) hold? Some algebra yields the following sufficient conditions:<br />

ε s > p<br />

tr +tp<br />

ε < p<br />

tr +tp<br />

where ε s and ε d are the elasticities of supply and demand, both defined to be positive. 34<br />

When demand is too elastic, or supply is too inelastic, the shift from posted to register taxes causes a<br />

net increase in the after-tax price of x. 35 Intuitively, this result emerges because the shift to register taxes<br />

is equivalent to a reduction in the elasticity of aggreg<strong>at</strong>e consumer demand. When demand is rel<strong>at</strong>ively<br />

elastic and supply is rel<strong>at</strong>ively inelastic, much of the posted tax will have been shifted onto producers.<br />

Hence the change in incidence due to the shift will be large. In contrast, when supply is rel<strong>at</strong>ively elastic<br />

and demand is rel<strong>at</strong>ively inelastic, the change in incidence will be small, and as a result, the revenue<br />

mechanism described in Part I will domin<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

34 These conditions are sufficient but not necessary for (20) to hold. In particular, as supply becomes more elastic, the<br />

elasticity of demand may be gre<strong>at</strong>er than p/(tr +tp) without (20) being viol<strong>at</strong>ed.<br />

35 Of course, consumers may ultim<strong>at</strong>ely benefit from the higher after-tax price when firms’ income is distributed to its<br />

owners and employees. The final distributive effects of the shift will thus depend on how producer income is divided between<br />

<strong>at</strong>tentive and in<strong>at</strong>tentive agents. Incorpor<strong>at</strong>ing such elements into the analysis is outside the scope of this paper.<br />

34<br />

(21)<br />

(22)


Appendix C: A Cognitive Cost Model of Heterogeneous Attentiveness<br />

How does <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes vary by income? The model we develop in this Appendix<br />

does not make a uniform prediction for all goods, but r<strong>at</strong>her highlights the factors th<strong>at</strong> determine which<br />

income group will be more <strong>at</strong>tentive for a particular good. We then consider those factors in the context<br />

of cigarettes to predict whether high- or low-income consumers are likely to be more <strong>at</strong>tentive to cigarette<br />

register taxes.<br />

Suppose all agents have the option of paying <strong>at</strong>tention to register taxes, but th<strong>at</strong> doing so carries with it<br />

some positive utility cost. 36 This "cognitive cost" could stem from the mental effort needed to remember<br />

and calcul<strong>at</strong>e a good’s tax-inclusive price or might simply represent the opportunity cost of time spent on<br />

th<strong>at</strong> task.<br />

Assume th<strong>at</strong> agents’ final utility is additively separable between the cognitive cost and consumption<br />

so th<strong>at</strong> we can write Wi = U (xi,yi) − bici in which bi is a binary choice variable indic<strong>at</strong>ing whether agent<br />

i pays the congitive cost and ci is the magnitude of the cost for agent i. We assume th<strong>at</strong> the cognitive cost<br />

is fixed for a given individual in th<strong>at</strong> it does not depend on the register tax r<strong>at</strong>e (it requires just as much<br />

effort to take a 6 cent register tax into account as a 7 cent one).<br />

The timing of the model with cognitive costs proceeds as in Part I, except here we add an initial step<br />

in which agents choose whether or not they will take register taxes into account when deciding on their<br />

consumption of x. As before, all agents choose an intended consumption bundle ( ˆx, ˆy) subject to their<br />

perceived budget constraint, which we can now express as BC : xi (p + bitr +tp) + yi ≤ Mi.<br />

A few final pieces of not<strong>at</strong>ion will be helpful. Let (x∗ i ,y∗i ) denote the (optimal) bundle th<strong>at</strong> i would<br />

consume if she were to pay <strong>at</strong>tention to the register tax and let ( ˜x, ˜y) denote the (sub-optimal) bundle she<br />

would consume were she to ignore the register tax. Agents who fail to pay the cognitive cost misperceive<br />

the after-tax price of x as being lower than it actually is; as a result, they over-spend on x and under-spend<br />

on y. The net change in i’s utility from taking the tax into account is therefore given by<br />

W (x ∗ i ,y ∗ i ,1) −W ( ˜xi, ˜yi,0) = Gi − ci<br />

where Gi ≡ U (x∗ i ,y∗i ) −U ( ˜x, ˜y) represents the agent’s utility gain from consuming the optimal feasible<br />

36 The cognitive cost model we use as our starting point follows the basic approach laid out in Chetty, Looney, Kroft (2007).<br />

35


undle.<br />

We assume th<strong>at</strong> agents opt to pay the cognitive cost when doing so affords them gre<strong>at</strong>er utility:<br />

bi = 1{Gi − ci ≥ 0}. Although a full-fledged comparison between the utility th<strong>at</strong> would be achieved in<br />

the two scenarios would likely require more cognitive effort than simply taking the tax into account in<br />

the first place, it seems reasonable th<strong>at</strong> the agents who decide to pay the cognitive cost tend to be the ones<br />

for whom doing so has the most benefit. 37<br />

Under the assumption th<strong>at</strong> utility is additively separable in x and y, Chetty, Looney, and Kroft (2007)<br />

show th<strong>at</strong> one can express Gi (the gain in consumption utility from taking the tax into account) as<br />

Gi = 1<br />

2 t2 εx,p x ∗ i v ′ (y ∗ <br />

1<br />

i ) + µiγi<br />

p +t<br />

where U(x,y) = u(x) + v(y), εx,p is the elasticity (defined to be positive) of x ∗ i<br />

with respect to its price,<br />

µi ≡ x∗ i<br />

y∗ represents the optimal r<strong>at</strong>io of x to y, and γi measures the curv<strong>at</strong>ure of v() <strong>at</strong> yi: γi ≡<br />

i<br />

−v′′ (y∗ i )<br />

v ′ (y∗ i ) y∗i .<br />

CLK allow differences in the extent to which individuals take taxes into account by assuming het-<br />

erogeneity in the cognitive costs th<strong>at</strong> agents face (ci), although they do not model the sources of th<strong>at</strong><br />

heterogeneity. Because our goal is to link differences in <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to agents’ income, we allow Gi<br />

to vary over individuals while abstracting from individual heterogeneity in cognitive costs: ci = c. 38 In<br />

particular, we focus on individual heterogeneity th<strong>at</strong> arises from differences in agents’ income. For a<br />

fixed tax r<strong>at</strong>e and price, we can write Gi as a function of the agent’s income(Mi)<br />

G(Mi) = 1<br />

2 t2 <br />

x∗ i (Mi)<br />

εx,p (Mi)<br />

p +t + µi<br />

<br />

(Mi)γi (Mi) v ′ (y ∗ i (Mi))<br />

The question we are interested in is whether low- or high-income individuals are more likely to take<br />

register taxes into account. Because agents are alike apart from their incomes, the question <strong>at</strong> hand is<br />

whether G(.) is increasing or decreasing in Mi. Differenti<strong>at</strong>ing the above expression with respect to<br />

37 Another justific<strong>at</strong>ion for this approach is th<strong>at</strong> agents might make a one-time comparison between Gi and ci to decide<br />

whether to pay the cognitive cost in future circumstance.<br />

38 In reality, cognitive costs may also be correl<strong>at</strong>ed with income. The correl<strong>at</strong>ion may be positive, if high earners are better<br />

<strong>at</strong> cognitive tasks of this sort, or neg<strong>at</strong>ive, if high earners have a gre<strong>at</strong>er opportunity cost of time. The extension to either of<br />

these cases is straightforward.<br />

36


income yields:<br />

∂Gi<br />

∂Mi<br />

= 1<br />

2 t2<br />

<br />

∂εx,p<br />

x<br />

∂Mi<br />

∗ i Av ′ (y ∗ i ) + ∂A<br />

εx,p x<br />

∂Mi<br />

∗ i v ′ (y ∗ i ) + ∂v′ (y∗ i )<br />

εx,p x<br />

∂Mi<br />

∗ <br />

i A + ∂x∗ i<br />

εx,p Av<br />

∂Mi<br />

′ (y ∗ i )<br />

where A = 1<br />

p+t + µi (Mi)γi (Mi). Since A, x∗ i , εx,p and v ′ (y∗ i ) are all positive, the key terms to sign are<br />

∂εx,p<br />

∂Mi<br />

∂A , ∂Mi , ∂x∗ i<br />

∂Mi , and ∂v′ (y∗ i )<br />

∂Mi<br />

.<br />

First, consider ∂v′ (y∗ i )<br />

. We know th<strong>at</strong> ∂Mi<br />

∂v′ (y∗ i )<br />

∂Mi = v′′ (y∗ i ) ∂y∗i ∂Mi<br />

< 0 assuming concave utility and th<strong>at</strong> y is<br />

a normal good. Intuitively, when the marginal utility of income declines rapidly with wealth, consumers<br />

who have little income to begin with are made much worse off by accidently over-spending on x.<br />

Second, consider ∂x∗ i . This term will be positive as long as x is a normal good, but will be smaller in<br />

∂Mi<br />

magnitude for goods for which consumption does not much change as income rises. In words, consumers<br />

who consume more will gain more from optimizing correctly simply because the consumption difference<br />

caused by the optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error will be larger in magnitude. When demand for x is rel<strong>at</strong>ively insensitive<br />

to income, contribution of this term will be small.<br />

Next consider ∂εx,p<br />

. Are high- or low-income consumers more price sensitive in their demand for x?<br />

∂Mi<br />

In general, theory is ambiguous as to whether elasticities rise or fall with income (the sign depends upon<br />

the magnitude of the third deriv<strong>at</strong>ive of the utility function with respect to x).<br />

Finally, consider ∂A ∂ µi = ∂Mi ∂Mi γi + ∂γi<br />

∂Mi µi. Let’s take the two pieces in turn. ∂x∗ i is clearly positive as long<br />

∂Mi<br />

as x is a normal good.<br />

∂ µi<br />

∂Mi<br />

refers to how the optimal r<strong>at</strong>io of x to y changes with income. This term is<br />

zero when preferences are homothetic and neg<strong>at</strong>ive for consumption goods th<strong>at</strong> constitute a larger share<br />

of expenditures for poor consumers than for rich consumers. The second term, ∂γi , captures change in<br />

∂Mi<br />

the curv<strong>at</strong>ure of utility from wealth as income rises; it will be weakly neg<strong>at</strong>ive when consumers exhibit<br />

constant or decreasing rel<strong>at</strong>ive risk aversion.<br />

We have highlighted the factors th<strong>at</strong> determine whether <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to a register tax is increasing or<br />

decreasing by income. Wh<strong>at</strong> does the analysis imply for the case of cigarettes? Regardless of the good in<br />

question, low-income consumers suffer more from lost consumption of other goods when they accidently<br />

overspend on the taxed good. The key determinants th<strong>at</strong> vary between goods are ∂x ∂εx,p ∂ µ<br />

, , and ∂Mi ∂Mi ∂Mi .<br />

For the case of cigarettes, all three of these factors suggest th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to register taxes should<br />

decrease by income. The income elasticity of cigarettes is generally found to be quite small (or even<br />

37


neg<strong>at</strong>ive), implying a low value for ∂x . Similarly, on average, poor households spend a substantially<br />

∂Mi<br />

larger fraction of their income on cigarettes compared to rich households (Chaloupka and Warner 2000),<br />

which implies th<strong>at</strong><br />

∂ µ<br />

∂εx,p<br />

< 0. Finally, the sign of ∂Mi ∂Mi<br />

hinges on whether low- or high-income consumers<br />

are more sensitive to cigarette prices. The empirical liter<strong>at</strong>ure on this question is mixed, with most<br />

studies concluding th<strong>at</strong> low-income smokers are slightly more price sensitive and other studies finding<br />

the opposite. In our d<strong>at</strong>a, we find the differences in price-sensitivity between rich and poor smokers to be<br />

negligible, implying th<strong>at</strong> ∂εx,p<br />

∂Mi<br />

is small in magnitude.<br />

As a whole, our model suggests th<strong>at</strong> <strong>at</strong>tentiveness to cigarette register taxes should decline by income.<br />

Low-income consumers suffer more when they over-spend on y because their marginal utility of wealth<br />

is gre<strong>at</strong>er than th<strong>at</strong> of high-income consumers. Although the magnitude of the optimiz<strong>at</strong>ion error will in<br />

general be larger for high-income consumers (the difference between their intended and realized bundles<br />

is bigger), this factor is mitig<strong>at</strong>ed in the case of cigarettes by the fact th<strong>at</strong> smoking demand is rel<strong>at</strong>ively<br />

insensitive to income and by the fact th<strong>at</strong> low-income consumers spend a substantially higher fraction of<br />

their income on cigarettes compared to high-income consumers.<br />

38


Table I: Summary of Cigarette Tax Changes<br />

Excise Tax Sales Tax Pre-Tax Price<br />

1984 2000 1984 2000 1984 2000<br />

Minimum 0.29 0.36 0.0 0.0 0.91 1.84<br />

Maximum 0.68 1.43 7.5 7.5 1.28 2.47<br />

Mean 0.50 0.75 3.8 5.0 1.03 2.20<br />

# St<strong>at</strong>e Changes 91 45<br />

# Federal Changes 3 n/a<br />

Excise tax and price are in 2000 dollars; sales tax in percent.<br />

39


Table II: Effect of Taxes on Cigarette Demand - Extensive and Intensive Margins<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Excise Tax -0.144 ∗∗∗ -0.116 ∗∗∗ -0.117 ∗∗∗ -6.588 ∗∗∗ -6.299 ∗∗∗ -6.546 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.034) (0.034) (0.035) (0.987) (0.985) (0.998)<br />

Sales Tax -0.404 ∗∗ -0.165 -0.165 -3.846 -2.608 -2.879<br />

(0.184) (0.133) (0.135) (5.233) (6.297) (6.408)<br />

Income -0.096 ∗∗∗ -0.096 ∗∗∗ -0.078 ∗∗∗ 0.004 0.003 1.756 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.005) (0.005) (0.009) (0.195) (0.195) (0.277)<br />

Female -0.041 ∗∗∗ -0.041 ∗∗∗ -0.041 ∗∗∗ -3.455 ∗∗∗ -3.455 ∗∗∗ -3.458 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.139) (0.140) (0.140)<br />

White 0.086 ∗∗∗ 0.086 ∗∗∗ 0.086 ∗∗∗ 6.404 ∗∗∗ 6.404 ∗∗∗ 6.405 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.172) (0.172) (0.171)<br />

H.S. Grad -0.057 ∗∗∗ -0.057 ∗∗∗ -0.057 ∗∗∗ -1.258 ∗∗∗ -1.258 ∗∗∗ -1.261 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.251) (0.251) (0.253)<br />

College Grad -0.121 ∗∗∗ -0.121 ∗∗∗ -0.121 ∗∗∗ -1.832 ∗∗∗ -1.833 ∗∗∗ -1.835 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.006) (0.006) (0.005) (0.160) (0.161) (0.162)<br />

Married -0.066 ∗∗∗ -0.066 ∗∗∗ -0.066 ∗∗∗ -0.369 ∗∗∗ -0.369 ∗∗∗ -0.360 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.083) (0.083) (0.084)<br />

Unemployed 0.087 ∗∗∗ 0.088 ∗∗∗ 0.088 ∗∗∗ 1.003 ∗∗∗ 1.004 ∗∗∗ 1.036 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.139) (0.138) (0.142)<br />

Age 0.034 ∗∗∗ 0.034 ∗∗∗ 0.034 ∗∗∗ -0.229 -0.228 -0.238<br />

(0.006) (0.006) (0.005) (0.229) (0.229) (0.230)<br />

Age2 -0.001 ∗∗∗ -0.001 ∗∗∗ -0.001 ∗∗∗ 0.028 ∗∗∗ 0.028 ∗∗∗ 0.029 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.008) (0.008) (0.008)<br />

Age3 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.001 ∗∗∗ -0.001 ∗∗∗ -0.001 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Age4 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 ∗∗∗ 0.000 ∗∗∗ 0.000 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)<br />

Log Unemp. R<strong>at</strong>e -0.031 ∗∗∗ -0.031 ∗∗∗ -0.128 -0.148<br />

(0.009) (0.009) (0.306) (0.307)<br />

Log St<strong>at</strong>e Income -0.012 -0.012 0.573 0.638<br />

(0.035) (0.035) (0.859) (0.849)<br />

Income Trend -0.002 -0.219 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.001) (0.027)<br />

Economic Conditions x x x x<br />

Income Trend x x<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 1.98 0.13 0.12 0.25 0.32 0.31<br />

prob>F 0.17 0.72 0.73 0.62 0.57 0.58<br />

N 934,106 934,106 934,106 198,914 198,914 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is for the test of equality between the excise tax and the sales tax coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

40


Table III: Effect of Taxes on Cigarette Demand - Overall Effect<br />

(1) (2) (3)<br />

Excise Tax -4.182 ∗∗∗ -3.586 ∗∗∗ -3.668 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.576) (0.578) (0.578)<br />

Sales Tax -8.414 ∗∗∗ -3.664 -3.731<br />

(2.397) (2.516) (2.513)<br />

Economic Conditions x x<br />

Income Trend x<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 2.82 0.00 0.00<br />

prob>F 0.09 0.98 0.98<br />

N 934,106 934,106 934,106<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics and st<strong>at</strong>e,<br />

year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is for the test of equality between the excise tax and the<br />

sales tax coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

41


Table IV: Effect of Taxes on Cigarette Demand by Income - Extensive and Intensive Margins<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Excise Tax -0.165 ∗∗∗ -0.136 ∗∗∗ -0.128 ∗∗∗ -7.665 ∗∗∗ -7.379 ∗∗∗ -6.423 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.035) (0.036) (0.035) (1.102) (1.055) (1.077)<br />

Sales Tax -0.333 ∗ -0.094 -0.092 0.200 1.428 1.392<br />

(0.181) (0.160) (0.160) (5.885) (7.077) (7.234)<br />

Excise*Low-income 0.082 0.081 0.045 3.665 ∗ 3.672 ∗ -0.211<br />

(0.058) (0.059) (0.063) (1.974) (1.985) (2.518)<br />

Sales*Low-income -0.339 -0.337 -0.350 -16.690 ∗∗ -16.710 ∗∗ -17.579 ∗∗<br />

(0.229) (0.230) (0.219) (7.673) (7.666) (7.841)<br />

Income -0.123 ∗∗∗ -0.123 ∗∗∗ -0.106 ∗∗∗ -0.272 -0.272 1.533 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.006) (0.006) (0.011) (0.186) (0.186) (0.312)<br />

Income Trend -0.002 -0.232 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.001) (0.028)<br />

Economic Conditions x x x x<br />

Income Trend x x<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 3.53 3.44 3.13 7.07 7.11 5.24<br />

prob>F 0.07 0.07 0.09 0.01 0.01 0.03<br />

N 934,106 934,106 934,106 198,914 198,914 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the test for equality between the excise*low-income and sales*low-income<br />

interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

42


Table V: Effect of Taxes on Cigarette Demand by Income - Overall Effect<br />

(1) (2) (3)<br />

Excise Tax -4.802 ∗∗∗ -4.207 ∗∗∗ -3.843 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.597) (0.600) (0.599)<br />

Sales Tax -6.185 ∗∗∗ -1.445 -1.411<br />

(2.477) (2.598) (2.595)<br />

Excise*Low-income 2.360 ∗∗∗ 2.346 ∗∗∗ 0.789<br />

(0.664) (0.664) (0.666)<br />

Sales*Low-income -10.094 ∗∗∗ -10.062 ∗∗∗ -10.496 ∗∗∗<br />

(2.847) (2.848) (2.856)<br />

Income -2.367 -2.368 -1.642<br />

(0.093) (0.093) (0.162)<br />

Income Trend -0.089<br />

(0.013)<br />

Economic Conditions x x<br />

Income Trend x<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 15.32 15.20 12.58<br />

prob>F 0.00 0.00 0.00<br />

N 934,106 934,106 934,106<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics and<br />

st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the test for equality between the<br />

excise*low-income and sales*low-income interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

43


Table VI: Effect of Taxes on Cigarette Demand by Income Quartile<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

Excise Sales F-st<strong>at</strong> Excise Sales F-st<strong>at</strong><br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

Baseline (Q1) -0.098 -0.457 ∗∗ -6.460 ∗∗∗ -16.106 ∗∗<br />

(0.066) (0.187) (2.140) (6.772)<br />

Tax*Q2 -0.094 ∗ 0.114 1.24 1.773 15.169 1.59<br />

(0.048) (0.191) (0.27) (3.072) (9.823) (0.22)<br />

Tax*Q3 -0.041 0.447 2.24 -0.027 18.411 ∗ 4.67 ∗∗<br />

(0.079) (0.304) (0.14) (2.056) (9.428) (0.04)<br />

Tax*Q4 0.035 0.497 ∗∗ 5.04 ∗∗ -2.541 19.755 ∗∗ 6.63 ∗∗<br />

(0.079) (0.209) (0.03) (2.572) (8.270) (0.02)<br />

N 934,106 934,106 198,914 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses in columns 1, 2, 4, and 5.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics, economic conditions, income trend,<br />

and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

Tax*income quartile interactions represent the difference between th<strong>at</strong> income quartile’s sensitivity<br />

to the tax r<strong>at</strong>e and the baseline quartile’s sensitivity to the tax r<strong>at</strong>e.<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong>s are associ<strong>at</strong>ed with testing ρ2, j − ρ1, j = 0 for j in {2,3,4}.<br />

Prob>F in parentheses.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

44


Table VII: Sales Tax Exemptions for Cigarettes<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2)<br />

Excise Tax -0.134 ∗∗∗ -6.408 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.035) (1.041)<br />

Excise*Low-income 0.046 -0.245<br />

(0.063) (2.440)<br />

Sales Tax*Non-exempt -0.858 ∗∗∗ -0.249<br />

(0.292) (15.182)<br />

Sales*Low-income*Non-exempt -0.351 -17.094 ∗<br />

(0.292) (8.431)<br />

Sales Tax*Exempt -1.264 ∗∗ -23.665<br />

(0.519) (30.629)<br />

Sales*Low-income*Exempt -0.012 1.954<br />

(0.391) (15.944)<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 4.10 1.64<br />

prob>F 0.05 0.21<br />

N 934,106 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics, economic conditions,<br />

income trend, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is for the test of equality between the sales*low-income interaction between<br />

st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> exempt cigarettes from the sales tax and st<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> do not.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

45


Table VIII: St<strong>at</strong>es th<strong>at</strong> Tax All Other Types of Tobacco<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2)<br />

Excise Tax -0.077 ∗∗ -6.667 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.029) (1.801)<br />

Sales Tax 0.203 7.773<br />

(0.452) (23.677)<br />

Excise*Low-income 0.055 0.568<br />

(0.075) (1.960)<br />

Sales*Low-income -0.706 ∗∗ -19.148 ∗<br />

(0.310) (10.975)<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 5.30 3.23<br />

prob>F 0.03 0.08<br />

N 647,705 132,091<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics,<br />

economic conditions, income trend, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar<br />

month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the test for equality between the<br />

excise*low-income and sales*low-income interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

46


Table IX: Instrumenting for Price with Excise Tax - First Stage<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

Excise Tax 0.925 ∗∗∗ -0.349 ∗∗∗ 1.031 ∗∗∗ -0.399 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.197) (0.051) (0.187) (0.062)<br />

Sales Tax 0.474 ∗∗ -0.027 0.496 ∗∗ -0.051<br />

(0.190) (0.089) (0.204) (0.098)<br />

Excise*Low-income -0.042 ∗∗∗ 2.408 ∗∗∗ -0.053 ∗∗∗ 2.433 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.007) (0.069) (0.015) (0.074)<br />

Sales*Low-income 0.034 0.729 ∗∗ 0.033 0.724 ∗<br />

(0.025) (0.337) (0.036) (0.360)<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 53,670 369,687 75,383 77,424<br />

R 2 0.96 0.98 0.96 0.98<br />

N 934,106 934,106 198,914 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics, economic conditions,<br />

income trend, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

(1) and (3): Dependent variable = post-tax price<br />

(2) and (4): Dependent variable = post-tax price*low-income<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

47


Table X: Instrumenting for Cigarette Prices with Excise Tax<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4)<br />

OLS IV OLS IV<br />

Price -0.045 ∗∗ -0.132 ∗∗∗ -1.437 ∗∗ -6.288 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.017) (0.042) (0.543) (1.561)<br />

Sales Tax -0.075 -0.032 2.240 4.295<br />

(0.150) (0.163) (7.679) (6.972)<br />

Price*Low-income 0.015 0.018 -0.048 -0.196<br />

(0.018) (0.026) (0.780) (1.056)<br />

Sales*Low-income -0.351 -0.348 -18.052 ∗∗ -16.890 ∗∗<br />

(0.219) (0.217) (8.204) (7.530)<br />

F-test 2.87 2.84 4.92 5.05<br />

prob>F 0.10 0.09 0.03 0.02<br />

N 934,106 934,106 198,914 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics, economic conditions,<br />

income trend, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

Price includes the excise tax.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is for the test of equality between the price*low-income and sales*low-income<br />

interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

48


Table XI: Altern<strong>at</strong>ive Demand Models<br />

Linear Tobit<br />

(1) (2)<br />

Excise Tax -2.572 ∗∗∗ -17.919 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.716) (3.811)<br />

Sales Tax -1.522 -11.230<br />

(3.423) (16.833)<br />

Excise*Low-income 0.357 3.394<br />

(1.643) (6.099)<br />

Sales*Low-income -9.380 -25.840<br />

(5.643) (18.497)<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 2.72 2.36<br />

prob>F 0.11 0.12<br />

N 929,921 929,921<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

198,914 observ<strong>at</strong>ions have non-zero demand.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic<br />

characteristics, economic conditions, income trend,<br />

and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the test for equality<br />

between the excise*low-income and sales*low-income<br />

interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

49


Table XII: Timing<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)<br />

3 Month 6 Month 12 Month 3 Month 6 Month 12 Month<br />

Excise Tax -0.110 ∗∗∗ -0.095 ∗∗∗ -0.106 ∗∗∗ -7.169 ∗∗∗ -6.837 ∗∗∗ -5.638 ∗∗∗<br />

(0.034) (0.034) (0.036) (1.452) (1.547) (2.030)<br />

Sales Tax -0.156 -0.174 -0.181 -0.452 -0.433 1.031<br />

(0.152) (0.138) (0.124) (7.018) (6.012) (5.091)<br />

Excise*Low-income 0.029 0.010 0.018 0.513 0.498 1.242<br />

(0.066) (0.072) (0.082) (2.534) (2.599) (2.660)<br />

Sales*Low-income -0.322 -0.309 -0.305 ∗ -16.544 ∗∗ -17.463 ∗∗ -18.083 ∗∗<br />

(0.205) (0.191) (0.176) (7.139) (7.105) (7.171)<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 3.05 2.90 3.55 6.76 7.70 7.39<br />

prob>F 0.09 0.10 0.07 0.01 0.01 0.01<br />

N 931,523 928,840 923,148 198,183 197,413 195,865<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics, economic conditions, income trend, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and<br />

calendar month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the test for equality between the excise*low-income and sales*low-income interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

50


Table XIII: St<strong>at</strong>e Trends<br />

Extensive Margin Intensive Margin<br />

(1) (2)<br />

Excise Tax -0.005 -4.344 ∗<br />

(0.035) (2.290)<br />

Sales Tax 0.062 4.335<br />

(0.192) (9.842)<br />

Excise*Low-income 0.045 -0.253<br />

(0.064) (2.532)<br />

Sales*Low-income -0.347 -16.938 ∗∗<br />

(0.219) (7.920)<br />

F-st<strong>at</strong> 3.12 4.72<br />

prob>F 0.09 0.04<br />

N 934,106 198,914<br />

Standard errors clustered <strong>at</strong> the st<strong>at</strong>e level in parentheses.<br />

All specific<strong>at</strong>ions include individual demographic characteristics,<br />

economic conditions, income trend, and st<strong>at</strong>e, year, and calendar<br />

month fixed effects.<br />

The F-st<strong>at</strong> is associ<strong>at</strong>ed with the test for equality between the<br />

excise*low-income and sales*low-income interaction coefficients.<br />

∗ p < 0.10, ∗∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗∗ p < 0.01<br />

51


Figure I: Average Monthly Taxes, 1984-2000<br />

(a) Sales Tax (b) Excise Tax<br />

52


Figure II: Aggreg<strong>at</strong>e Cigarette Consumption<br />

53


Figure III: Smoking R<strong>at</strong>es by Income<br />

54

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!