02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Aggregating preference judgments 319<br />

scale are shown below and it can be seen that San Francisco would now<br />

be the group choice.<br />

Destination Person A Person B Average<br />

Rio de Janeiro 40 50 45<br />

San Francisco 16 100 58<br />

Toronto 0 0 0<br />

Is it possible to compare one individual’s strength of preference<br />

with another’s? French 11 examines a number of ways in which such<br />

comparisons could be made in theory and shows that all the methods<br />

are likely to fail in practice. For example, the whole group might agree<br />

unanimously that person 1 prefers P to Q more than person 2 prefers<br />

X to Y. But what would happen in the likely event of this unanimity<br />

not being achieved? Alternatively, we might use money as the common<br />

yardstick for strength of preference. If person A is only prepared to pay<br />

$100 to transfer from his worst to his best holiday destination while<br />

person B is prepared to pay $1500 then can we say that B’s strength of<br />

preference is greater than A’s? If we answer yes to this question then we<br />

must assume that $1 is equally valued by the two people, but what if A is<br />

a pauper and B a millionaire? Clearly, our ‘objective’ scale would lead us<br />

back to the problem of comparing individuals’ strengths of preference!<br />

In the absence of any obvious method for making interpersonal<br />

comparisons of intensity of preference then it seems that our search<br />

for a group value or utility function is futile. Nevertheless, the concepts<br />

of value and utility can still be useful in group decision making. The<br />

derivation of individual values and utilities can help each group member<br />

to clarify his or her personal understanding of the problem and also to<br />

achieve a greater appreciation of the views of other members. Moreover,<br />

a simple average of values and utilities may be useful in providing<br />

a rough initial model of the problem. Sensitivity analysis can then be<br />

used to test the effect of using individual values and utilities. This may<br />

reveal, for example, that certain options are to be preferred to others,<br />

irrespective of which individual’s utility function is used. At the very<br />

least, the process should lead to a more informed discussion and debate.<br />

This reference to group discussion and debate leads us to the next<br />

section, where behavioral aggregation methods are considered. We begin<br />

by looking at the behavioral problems which can occur when a group of<br />

decision makers meet to agree upon a course of action.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!