02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

310 Decisions involving groups of individuals<br />

Two simple advantages arise from obtaining group judgments in<br />

decision analysis. First, more information about possible ranges of<br />

utilities and probabilities can be obtained, and it is then possible to<br />

perform sensitivity analysis on these ranges to see if the decision specified<br />

by the analysis is changed by these variations. Second, a group of<br />

people who are involved in such a decision process may become more<br />

committed to implementing the decision which is eventually made. As<br />

we shall see in the section on decision conferencing, this latter advantage<br />

can be a major one.<br />

Mathematical aggregation<br />

Ferrell 1 provides an excellent and comprehensive discussion of mathematical<br />

and other aggregation methods. Much of the following discussion<br />

is based on his review.<br />

There are a number of advantages to be gained by using mathematical<br />

aggregation to combine the judgments of the individual members of<br />

a group. In particular, the methods involved are relatively straightforward.<br />

For example, we might ask each member of a group to estimate<br />

the probability that the sales of a product will exceed 10 000 units next<br />

year and then calculate a simple average of their estimates. This means<br />

that the more complex and time-consuming procedures of behavioral<br />

aggregation are avoided. Moreover, the group members do not have to<br />

meet. Their judgments can be elicited by telephone, post or computer and<br />

therefore the influence of dominant group members is avoided. However,<br />

there can be serious problems with the mathematical approach as<br />

the following, rather contrived, example shows.<br />

Suppose that a production manager and an accountant have to make<br />

a joint decision between investing in a large- or small-volume processor.<br />

The payoff of the processor will depend upon the average level of<br />

sales which will be achieved during its useful life. Table 12.1 shows the<br />

production manager’s subjective probabilities for the sales levels and his<br />

utilities for the different actions and outcomes. It can be seen that the<br />

expected utility of a high-volume processor is 0.4 (i.e. 0.4 × 1 + 0.6 × 0)<br />

while for the low-volume processor it is 0.412 (i.e. 0.4 × 0.1 + 0.6 × 0.62),<br />

so the production manager will just prefer the low-volume processor.<br />

Table 12.2 shows the accountant’s view of the problem. Her expected<br />

utilities are 0.5 for the high-volume processor and 0.51 for the lowvolume<br />

one so she will also favor the low-volume processor. However,<br />

if we now take the average of the probabilities and utilities of the two

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!