02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Applying simulation to investment decisions 203<br />

It can be seen from these results that simulation enables a more<br />

informed choice to be made between investment opportunities. By<br />

restricting us to single-value estimates the conventional NPV approach<br />

yields no information on the level of uncertainty which is associated<br />

with different options. Hespos and Strassman 7 have shown how the<br />

simulation approach can be extended to handle investment problems<br />

involving sequences of decisions using a method known as stochastic<br />

decision tree analysis.<br />

Utility and net present value<br />

In order to help a decision maker to choose between a number of<br />

alternative investment projects we could obtain a utility function for net<br />

present value. This would involve giving the highest possible NPV a<br />

utility of 1, the lowest a utility of 0 and the use of questions involving<br />

lotteries to determine the utilities of intermediate NPVs. The decision<br />

maker would then be advised to choose the investment project which<br />

had the highest expected utility. The question is, how justified would<br />

we be in converting NPVs to utilities? As we demonstrate below, to use<br />

NPVs we need to make some strong assumptions about the decision<br />

maker’s preferences.<br />

First, the use of the NPV approach implies that the decision maker’s<br />

relative strength of preference for receiving money in any two adjacent<br />

years is the same, whatever those years are. For example, if a 10%<br />

discount rate is used it implies that $1 receivable in one year’s time is<br />

equivalent to receiving about $0.91 today. Similarly, $1 receivable in<br />

10 years’ time is equivalent to receiving $0.91 in 9 years’ time. Now it<br />

may well be that a decision maker has a very strong relative preference<br />

for receiving money now rather than in a year’s time, while his or her<br />

relative preference between receiving a sum in 9 as opposed to 10 years<br />

is much weaker.<br />

Second, if we consider the decision maker’s relative preference for<br />

sums of money between the same pair of years it can be seen that the<br />

NPV method assumes a constant rate of trade-off between the years.<br />

For example (again assuming a 10% discount rate), it assumes that you<br />

would be prepared to give up the promise of $1 in a year’s time in<br />

order to receive $0.91 today, and that you would be prepared to go<br />

on making this exchange, irrespective of the amount of money which<br />

is transferred from next year to this. Again, this may not be the case.<br />

You may be desperate for $10 000 now and be prepared to give up the<br />

promise of £3 in a year’s time for each $0.91 you can receive today. Once

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!