02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

196 Applying simulation to decision problems<br />

to minimize the risk or uncertainty which her company faces. If we<br />

compare products A and B we see that, while they offer the same<br />

expected return, product B is much more risky. Product A is therefore<br />

said to dominate B. B is also dominated by C, which for the same level<br />

of risk offers higher expected profits. For the same reason, D dominates<br />

E. The non-dominated products, A, C and D, are therefore said to lie<br />

on the efficient frontier, and only these products would survive the<br />

screening process and be considered further. The choice between A, C<br />

and D will depend on how risk averse the decision maker is. Product<br />

A offers a low expected return but also a low level of risk, while at the<br />

other extreme, C offers high expected returns but a high level of risk.<br />

The utility approach, which we discussed above, could now be used to<br />

compare these three products.<br />

Note that for the mean–standard deviation screening process to be<br />

valid it can be shown that a number of assumptions need to be made.<br />

First, the probability distributions for profit should be fairly close to<br />

the normal distribution shape shown in Figure 7.9(a) (in many practical<br />

situations this is likely to be the case: see Hertz and Thomas 1 ). Second, the<br />

decision maker should have a utility function which not only indicates<br />

risk aversion but which also has (at least approximately) a quadratic<br />

form. This means that the function can be represented by an equation of<br />

the form:<br />

U(x) = c + bx + ax 2<br />

where x = a given sum of money, U(x) = the utility of this sum of money<br />

and a, b and c are other numbers which determine the exact nature of<br />

the utility function.<br />

For example, Figure 7.9(b) shows the utility functions<br />

and<br />

U(x) = 0 + 0.4x − 0.04x 2<br />

U(x) = 0 + 0.25x − 0.01x 2<br />

(where x = monetary sums in millions of dollars) for monetary values<br />

between $0 and $5 million. Of course, not all utility functions have the<br />

quadratic form, but as Markowitz 4 argues, ‘the quadratic nevertheless<br />

shows a surprising flexibility in approximating smooth, concave curves’.<br />

Having considered the different ways in which the results of simulations<br />

can be compared, how was a decision made in the case of<br />

the Elite Pottery Company? First, it was established that the Managing<br />

Director’s utility function for profit was concave (i.e. he was risk

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!