02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

118 Decision making under uncertainty<br />

we could either ask the decision maker how much he would be prepared<br />

to pay to buy the lottery ticket or, assuming that he already owns the<br />

ticket, how much he would accept to sell it. Research suggests that people<br />

tend to offer a lower price to buy the ticket than they would accept to<br />

sell it. There is thus a propensity to prefer the status quo, so that people<br />

are generally happier to retain a given risk than to take the same risk<br />

on (see also Thaler 6 ). Finally, the context in which the questions were<br />

framed was found to have an effect on responses. For example, Hershey<br />

et al. 5 refer to an earlier experiment when the same choice was posed in<br />

different ways, the first involving an insurance decision and the second<br />

a gamble as shown below:<br />

Insurance formulation<br />

Situation A: You stand a one out of a thousand chance of losing $1000.<br />

Situation B: You can buy insurance for $10 to protect you from this loss.<br />

Gamble formulation<br />

Situation A: You stand a one out of a thousand chance of losing $1000.<br />

Situation B: You will lose $10 with certainty.<br />

It was found that 81% of subjects preferred B in the insurance formulation,<br />

while only 56% preferred B in the gamble formulation.<br />

Tversky and Kahneman 7 provide further evidence that the way in<br />

which the choice is framed affects the decision maker’s response. They<br />

found that choices involving statements about gains tend to produce<br />

risk-averse responses, while those involving losses are often risk seeking.<br />

For example, in an experiment subjects were asked to choose a program<br />

to combat a disease which was otherwise expected to kill 600 people.<br />

One group was told that Program A would certainly save 200 lives<br />

while Program B offered a 1/3 probability of saving all 600 people and a<br />

2/3 probability of saving nobody. Most subjects preferred A. A second<br />

group were offered the equivalent choice, but this time the statements<br />

referred to the number of deaths, rather than lives saved. They were<br />

therefore told that the first program would lead to 400 deaths while the<br />

second would offer a 1/3 probability of no deaths and a 2/3 probability<br />

of 600 deaths. Most subjects in this group preferred the second program,<br />

which clearly carries the higher risk. Further experimental evidence that<br />

different assessment methods lead to different utilities can be found in a<br />

paper by Johnson and Schkade. 8<br />

What are the implications of this research for utility assessment? First,<br />

it is clear that utility assessment requires effort and commitment from<br />

the decision maker. This suggests that, before the actual elicitation takes<br />

place, there should be a pre-analysis phase in which the importance of

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!