02.03.2013 Views

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

Downloadable - About University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Interpreting utility functions 109<br />

Utility<br />

1.0<br />

0.8<br />

0.6<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

−10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Money ($000)<br />

Figure 5.5 – A utility function for the conference organizer<br />

Increase<br />

in utility<br />

through<br />

winning<br />

Decrease<br />

in utility<br />

through<br />

losing the<br />

gamble<br />

Utility<br />

1.0<br />

0.8<br />

0.6<br />

0.4<br />

0.2<br />

0<br />

0 1000 2000<br />

Money ($)<br />

Figure 5.6 – A utility function demonstrating risk aversion<br />

0.5 × $2000 + 0.5 × $0), so according to the EMV criterion he should be<br />

indifferent between keeping his money and gambling. However, when<br />

we apply the utility function to the decision we see that currently the<br />

decision maker has assets with a utility of 0.9. If he gambles he has a<br />

50% chance of increasing his assets so that their utility would increase<br />

to 1.0 and a 50% chance of ending with assets with a utility of 0. Hence<br />

the expected utility of the gamble is 0.5 × 1 + 0.5 × 0, which equals 0.5.<br />

Clearly, the certain money is more attractive than the risky option of<br />

gambling. In simple terms, even though the potential wins and losses

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!