25.08.2013 Aufrufe

Nachhaltiges Europa Abschlusspublikation - Global Marshall Plan

Nachhaltiges Europa Abschlusspublikation - Global Marshall Plan

Nachhaltiges Europa Abschlusspublikation - Global Marshall Plan

MEHR ANZEIGEN
WENIGER ANZEIGEN

Erfolgreiche ePaper selbst erstellen

Machen Sie aus Ihren PDF Publikationen ein blätterbares Flipbook mit unserer einzigartigen Google optimierten e-Paper Software.

ecord performances would not happen if every-<br />

body practised their sports alone or in small<br />

groups. In exactly the same way industrial and<br />

technological innovation does not happen auto-<br />

matically. It is part of a struggle against others to<br />

win customers, and if the struggle is world-wide<br />

the standard that has to be beaten is a high one.<br />

You might argue, as it has sometimes been the<br />

case in education circles, that if in a class of 20<br />

only one child can win a race and all the others<br />

“lose”, then it is better not to have a race at all. I<br />

don’t think that’s right. You may come last in running<br />

and be first in the astronomy club. Coming<br />

last is still good if you ran faster than last time<br />

(and if you enjoyed the training, and improved<br />

your health etc). The benefits of competition are<br />

not confined to the gold medal winners. Millions<br />

and millions of individuals derive the benefits from<br />

competing in a sport discipline, but only one individual<br />

gets the gold medal.<br />

It’s pretty much the same with economic activity:<br />

I am inclined to think that we can afford to see<br />

different gold medallists in different areas of activity,<br />

and at different times. As a country you don’t<br />

have to get the gold medal in every sport to enjoy<br />

the benefits of competing in them. As standards of<br />

living catch up in other countries, we can expect to<br />

see their share of gold medal winners – both on<br />

our TVs and on the manufacturers label on those<br />

TVs - creep up as well.<br />

Some warn against the dangers of losing a manufacturing<br />

base to one’s economy. But I don’t think<br />

that we should worry unduly about the material<br />

consequences for ourselves of seeing some new<br />

faces on the winners’ podium for traditional manufacturing<br />

sectors. Reports like the recent one by<br />

CEPII, or press articles that ask what is left for us<br />

once India and China have realised their potential,<br />

all rest on questioning what is in fact a vital<br />

notion: that economics is not a zero-sum game.<br />

They rest on a defeatist and depressing belief that<br />

there is no room for us all to enjoy good standards<br />

of living; that there is a limited place in the sun<br />

and we all have to use our elbows. In this they are<br />

probably motivated more by a concern about selfesteem<br />

– about a future with fewer gold medals -<br />

than a genuine economic concern. This leads to<br />

phoney arguments like the argument that manufacturing<br />

industry is more important than services<br />

because productivity gains are easier to obtain.<br />

Friends, if a productivity gain is cancelled out by<br />

falling prices, its impact on living standards is nil.<br />

The CEPII report points very clearly to certain de-<br />

velopments which it anticipates will underlie the<br />

convergence of the BRIC countries (Brazil, India,<br />

China) with the highest existing standards:<br />

<strong>Nachhaltiges</strong> <strong>Europa</strong><br />

- China is looking to scoop gold on textiles and<br />

wood and paper-based products.<br />

- Brazil will be the agricultural champion as the<br />

playing field is levelled, and turn iron and steel<br />

into silvers and bronzes.<br />

- India will compete hard on textiles, and mechanical<br />

engineering, chemicals and steel.<br />

But despite these broad trends it is also clear that<br />

the idea of an international division of labour<br />

whereby the North specialises in recent technological<br />

industries like IT and communications, and<br />

the South capitalises on its strengths in traditional<br />

sectors like textiles and toys is no longer valid.<br />

The South will compete on everything. Only really<br />

in some fast-changing and capital-intensive sectors<br />

like aeronautics, electric components, and<br />

automobiles will the North resist the pull of the<br />

South better.<br />

Bear in mind though, that the markets for much of<br />

this production will also be in the South. Whilst<br />

CEPII worries that BRIC countries have the ability<br />

to sustain lower wage levels for a long time, it is<br />

clear that their societies will be transformed by<br />

higher levels of material consumption which can<br />

benefit us. At last somebody in the US government<br />

has spotted this upside, and pointed out that<br />

globalisation creates jobs in the US too. Elaine<br />

Chao, the US Labor Secretary, pointed out on September<br />

1 st this year that whilst around 300,000<br />

jobs have been eliminated in favour of cheaper la-<br />

bour elsewhere, there are around 9 million Americans<br />

working for US subsidiaries of foreign-owned<br />

companies. Remember too that in some cases the<br />

companies overseeing the production in the South<br />

will be controlled here in the North. Not that control<br />

needs to be the issue that it has been in the<br />

past. The international interdependency from inte-<br />

gration means that loss of control is not posed in<br />

same terms as in the past.<br />

A greater and a more balanced international inter-<br />

dependency in fact only restores a better balance<br />

that used to exist. According to Angus Maddison,<br />

the economic historian, in the early 19th century<br />

Asia generated about 60 per cent of world output<br />

(measured at purchasing power parity), with China<br />

alone generating a third and India a sixth. Then<br />

began a century and a half of stagnation, with the<br />

exception only of Japan. By 1950 Asia's share of<br />

global gross domestic product had fallen from<br />

three fifths to below one fifth. Then between 1950<br />

and 1973 Asia's share in world gross domestic<br />

product rose from a fifth to a quarter, almost<br />

entirely because of Japan's dynamism. By 2001 it<br />

had risen to two fifths, with China's share rising<br />

from 5 per cent in 1973 to 12 per cent in 2001<br />

45

Hurra! Ihre Datei wurde hochgeladen und ist bereit für die Veröffentlichung.

Erfolgreich gespeichert!

Leider ist etwas schief gelaufen!